RECENT AMENDMENTS TO THE KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AND THEIR EFFECTS ON INTERNATIONAL COMPETITION



RECENT AMENDMENTS TO THE KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AND THEIR EFFECTS ON INTERNATIONAL COMPETITION



Description:
The recent revisions to the Commercial Code and their effects in Korea’s corporate regulatory environment


JOONGI KIM

1. INTRODUCTION: SEARCHING FOR THE ORIGINS OF THE CRISIS

Corporate law in Korea has undergone a dramatic transformation in recent years. In an effort to revamp Korean corporations, the Korean government made sweeping reforms to Korea’s Commercial Code (sang-bup) three times in the past four years – in 1995, 1998, and 1999.1 These newly amended provisions have set in mo¬tion unprecedented changes for the Korean corporate environment. Korean management is finally beginning to be monitored and cha l

* Assistant Professor of Law, Graduate School of International Studies (GSIS), Yonsei University, Seoul, Korea

1 See Commercial Code, Law No. 1000 of 1962 (as amended Law No. 5053 of 1995, Law No. 5591 of 1998 and Law No. 6086 of 2000) (“KCC”). The cor¬porate law section of Korea’s Commercial Code can be found between Articles 169 and 637. In this Article, the changes will be referred to as “1995 KCC,” “1998 KCC,” and “1999 KCC” respectively, and simply “KCC” if no changes were made in 1995, 1998, or 1999. For a critical view on how the KCC and the Securities Exchange Act (“SEA”) should be amended to harmonize each other, see Ki-won Choi, IMF ui geuk-bok-eul wui-han sang-bup-gae -jung bang-hyang (I) [How the Korean Commercial Code Should Be Amended to Overcome the IMF Situation (I) ], L. TIMES (Seoul), Apr. 13, 1998, at 14.

Other major laws that can apply to corporations include the Civil Code, the SEA, the Securities Investment Trust Business Act, the Securities Investment Company Act, the Foreign Exchange Trade Act, the Bankruptcy Act, and the Composition Act. See Securities Investment Company Act, Law No. 5557 of 1998 (as amended Law No. 6174 of 2000)

273

lenged in a more meaningful manner, while at the same time, di¬rectors and auditors have gained both renewed authority and re¬sponsibilities. Shareholder rights have been strengthened to levels previously unimaginable by Korean standards. 2 The number of mergers and acquisitions has risen noticeably, and unfriendly cor¬porate takeovers have even been attempted.3 Although still far from international standards, these new corporate regulations not only can assist other industrializing countries that are contemplating similar regulatory changes, but they can also contribute to the de¬bate surrounding the potential for global convergence in corporate

4

governance.

More specifically, the 1995 amendments (“1995 KCC”) marked only the second time that Korea amended its corporate law section of the KCC since the KCC’s initial enactment in 1962.5 The 1995 amendments attempted to address a broad range of issues including

2 See infra Section 3.3.

3 See KOREA FAIR TRADE COMM’N, TONG-GYE-YON-BO [ANNUAL

STATISTICS], Mar. 26, 1999 (visited Apr. 10, 2000) <http://www.ftc.go.kr>. See infra Section 4.2 for examples of recent unfriendly takeover attempts. The num¬ber of mergers filed with the Korea Fair Trade Commission that involved comp a¬nies with total assets or sales greater than 100 billion won (U.S. $83 million) were as fo llows:

1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999

Merger

Filings 62 55 48 48 63 75 151 145

4 Malaysia, Indonesia, and Thailand are some other countries that are pur¬suing reform in their corporate governance regulations. See ANDREW STONE ET

AL., THE BUSINESS ENVIRONMENT AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE: STRENGTHENING INCENTIVES FOR PRIVATE SECTOR PERFORMANCE, 6-7 (1998)

(visited Apr. 16, 2000) <http://www.worldbank.org/html/fpd/ privatesec¬tor/cg/docs/busenvp8.pdf> (one of five papers prepared by World Bank staff for their 1998 annual meeting)

5 But see Ki-won Choi, Sang-bup-gae -jung-an-ui moon -jae -jum [The Prob¬lems with the Proposal to Amend the Commercial Code], L. TIMES (Seoul), June 13, 1994, at 14 (suggesting that the Commercial Code was being revised too fre¬quently). The last time the corporate law section of the KCC was substantively amended occurred in 1984. See Law No. 3724 of 1984. See generally Gil -jun Park, Gae -jung-sang-bup-hae-sul [Explanation of the Amended Commercial Code], Jeung-gwon, Mar. 1984, at 37 (providing background on the 1984 amendments to the KCC).

shareholder rights, the regulation of mergers and acquisitions, and the role of directors and auditors. Many of these changes had been long advocated, but were often delayed under the pretext that cor¬porations were not ready.6 Before the impact of the 1995 KCC could fully be measured, however, Korea’s economy plunged into one of the worst recessions in its history, falling victim to the finan¬cial contagion that swept across most of Asia in 1997.7

The 1997 financial crisis exposed a wide range of structural weaknesses in Korea’s economy. International organizations such as the International Monetary Fund (“IMF”) and the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (“World Bank”), in par¬ticular, criticized Korea’s corporate sector and blamed ineffective corporate regulation as a major cause of the crisis. 8 In addition to corporate sector reforms, such as corporate financial restructuring and corporate governance, the World Bank and IMF also cited

6 See Hee-chul Chung, Sang-bup-gae -jung-si-an-ui moon -jae -jum [Problems with the Proposed Amendments to the Commercial Code], 23 BUP-HAK [herein¬after SEOUL L.J.] 1 (1982) [hereinafter Hee-chul Chung, Problems]

7 See generally TOMÁS J.T. BALIÑO & ANGEL UBIDE, THE KOREAN FINANCIAL CRISIS OF 1997 -A STRATEGY OF FINANCIAL SECTOR REFORM (Inter

national Monetary Fund Working Paper No. WP/99/28, 1999) (providing a com¬prehensive view on the origins of the crisis and how it affected Korea)

8 See BALIÑO & UBIDE, supra note 7, at 7 (“[L]ack of transparency in finan¬cial and corporate sectors, weak governance, and poor regulatory systems ham¬pered the efficient functioning of markets in disciplining the Korean economy.”). In its “Letter of Development Policy” concerning the Second Structural Adjust¬ment Loan from the World Bank, the Korean government admitted that “[t]o re¬store, and sustain, financial viability and competitiveness, Korean firms need both financial and real restructuring. The latter requires improvements in the governance of firms and increased exposure to competitive pressures.” Letter from Kyu-Sung Lee, Minister of Finance and Economy, to James D. Wolfensohn, President, International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, para. 7 (Sept. 24, 1998), <http://www.worldbank.org/html/ extdr/offrep/eap/krsalii/ldp.html> [hereinafter Letter from Kyu-Sung Lee].

structural problems related to macroeconomic reforms, financial sector reforms, and labor reforms.9 In return for receiving their fi¬nancial assistance, Korea enacted another round of extensive amendments to its corporate laws on December 28, 1998 (“1998 KCC”).10 While the 1998 KCC arose out of unfortunate circum¬stances, the financial crisis provided the impetus to further overhaul the KCC and implement reforms that remained unfinished after the 1995 amendments. Finally, on December 31, 1999, several addi¬tional amendments were enacted (“1999 KCC”). Although not as extensive, the 1999 KCC in particular included new provisions governing stock options and audit committees.

This background provides an appropriate juncture at which to assess the impact and potential of the 1995, 1998, and 1999 amendments to the KCC. This Article will begin with a discussion of the major problems that previously existed in corporate regula¬tion. It will seek to show that these shortcomings not only left Ko¬rean corporations uncompetitive, but also vulnerable to external shocks. Next, the Article will review, in depth, the major amend¬ments that were recently made to the KCC.11 The upshot of these new laws will then be examined through several recent case studies. Lastly, some of the major unresolved issues will be explored.

Overall, this Article will conclude that the recent changes to the KCC are reshaping the Korean corporate environment in an un

9 See BALIÑO & UBIDE, supra note 7

10 See Letter from Kyu-Sung Lee, supra note 8

11 The KCC provides for four types of companies: hap -ja-hwoe-sa (limited partnerships), hap-myung-hwoe-sa (general partnerships), yoo-han-hwoe-sa (lim¬ited liability companies), and joo-shik-hwoe-sa (stock corporations). See KCC art. 170. This Article will focus on the changes to stock corporations, which ac¬count for more than 92% of all companies in Korea. See CHUL-SONG LEE,

SANG-BUP-GANG-UI [LECTURES ON THE COMMERCIAL CODE] 251 (1997). See

KCC articles 288 to 542 for the provisions in the KCC that primarily govern stock corporations.

precedented fashion. For the first time, firms must establish more effective checks and balances, and become more transparent and accountable. While some reforms still languish, these changes have set into motion a reorientation of the governance structure of Kore¬an corporations. The recent measures, as a whole, will help enhan¬ce the competitiveness of corporate Korea and allow it to become a more serious contender in the international marketplace.

2. THE SHORTCOMINGS OF CORPORATE KOREA

Not many countries can claim the type of post-war economic success that Korea has achieved. By the end of 1996, Korea beca¬me the eleventh largest economy, with a per capita income of over U.S. $10,000 in the span of three decades. When the 1997 financial crisis hit, however, the economy and corporate Korea alike col¬lapsed, unable to withstand the shocks of the crisis. Korean corpo¬rations, therefore, stand at a critical crossroad because they must find a way to resolve the inherent weaknesses that were exposed during the crisis.

Most of the faults in Korean corporations can be traced to the failure of the corporate regulatory framework. In essence, the man¬agement structure established to oversee business firms did not function as expected.12 Corporate actors, such as shareholders, the board of directors, representative directors, and auditors, did not fulfill their respective statutory duties.13 One expert describes the

12 In addition to internal corporate governance, Korean companies also suf¬fered from weak external governance. An active mergers and acquisitions market did not exist, bankruptcies were difficult to pursue, external accounting oversight was rare, and banks failed to properly control lending practices. See Seung-min Yoo, Dae-gi-up gyung-young-goo -jo-ui moon -jae -jum-gwa gae-sun-bang-an [Problems of, and a Proposal to Improve, the Management Structure of Large Corporations], 36 SANG-JANG-HYUP 11, 18 (1997) (discussing the lack of moni¬toring by creditors). See generally Michael Schuman, Piling On: For Korea’s Banks, Hanbo Is Merely the Latest Shock, ASIAN WALL ST. J., Feb. 3, 1997, at 1 [hereinafter Schuman, Piling On]

13 The board of directors system was adopted from the Japanese system, which, in turn, was based on the U.S. system. See Dong-yoon Chung, Sang-bup sa-ship-oh-nyun: ge hwoe-go wa jun-mang [45 Years of the Korean Commercial Code: Its Past and Future], in HAN-GOOK BUP-HAK UI HWOE-GO WA JUN¬MANG [THE PAST AND FUTURE OF KOREAN LAW] 343, 356 (1991)

Thomas L. Blakemore & Makoto Yazawa, Japanese Commercial Code Revi¬sions: Concerning Corporations, 2 AM. J. COMP. L. 12, 12, 15-16 (1953) (“On a

anomalous situation whereby Korean boards would monitor the m¬selves as being functionally in between the dual-board system or two-tier system of Germany, and the single-board or one-tier sys¬tem of the United States.14 Shareholders, whether they were indi¬vidual or institutional investors, did not monitor corporate affairs. Directors and auditors, in turn, had little incentive to act as respon¬sible fiduciaries on behalf of the interests of all shareholders.

Over time, an ineffective system of corporate governance emerged that was saddled with opaque business practices and an overall lack of checks and balances.15 Under this lax management structure, principal shareholders have dominated the affairs of the corporation, serving as both chief owner and manager. Eventually, this unchallenged rule by corporate chieftains created enormous agency costs and left Korean corporations structurally vulnerable and uncompetitive.

2.1. Dominant Principal Shareholders and Inefective Boards of Directors, Representative Directors, and Auditors

For most publicly held companies in Korea, principal share¬holders unilaterally dictated corporate policy.16 These principal

Commercial Code of continental origin, there have been forcibly grafted certain limbs of alien, Anglo-American origin.”)

14 See Chan-hyung Chung, Gi-up-gyung -young-ui too-myung-sung -jae-go¬reul wui-han joo-Shik-hwoe-sa-ui ji-bae-goo -jo-ui gae-sun (I) [Improving Cor¬porate Governance of Stock Corporations to Enhance Transparency of Corpo¬rate Management (I) ], L. TIMES (Seoul), May 7, 1998, at 14.

15 See Dae-hong Chang, Joo -joo -joong-shi gyong -young-gwa gi-up -ji-bae¬goo -jo gae-sun [Management that Places Importance on Shareholders and Im¬proving Corporate Governance], 39 SANG-JANG-HYUP 36 (1999)

16 See Jong-ho Na & Young-shin Yoon, Chae-bol gae-hyuk (2) [Reform of the Chaebol (2)], CHOSUN ILBO (Seoul), Jan. 3, 1998, at 11. A classic example occurred in 1994 when the Chairman of the Dong Ah group unilaterally an¬nounced, without considering shareholder interests, that his construction com¬pany accepted moral responsibility for a collapsed bridge and would donate 150 billion won (U.S. $125 million) to the city of Seoul to rebuild it. See Hyo-sang Kang, Dae-gi-up oh-nuh ‘dok -joo’ man-ta [Many Owners of Large Conglomer¬ates Act “Unilaterally”], CHOSUN ILBO, May 10, 1996, at 11

shareholders dominated corporate affairs without any checks or bal¬ances in place regarding their decisions, unaccountable to anyone but themselves.17 In essence, they naturally placed their interests above the interests of the other shareholders because no pressure existed to act otherwise, creating an enormous agency problem.

Principal shareholders commanded all facets of corporate affairs, including board decisions, the selection of directors or auditors, and shareholders’ meetings.18 Principal shareholders single-handedly appointed directors and auditors. Candidates were selected from company employees, with one of the most important criteria being personal loyalty to the principal shareholders.19 Those nominated for director and auditor positions were then universally approved at shareholders’ meetings.

As a result, directors and auditors, thus held captive, could not act independently from principal shareholders in carrying out their respective functions. The board of directors did not make decisions on behalf of the corporation, but instead gave strong preference to the inclinations or passions of the principal shareholders.20 The

17 See Keo-san Lee & Young-shin Yoon, Chae-bol gae-hyuk (7) [Reform of the Chaebol (7)], CHOSUN ILBO, Jan. 8, 1998, at 9

18 Outside directors or auditors, on the other hand, did not exist until recently. The Korea Stock Exchange (“KSE”) required listed companies to elect one out¬side director in 1998 and to have outside directors comprise 25% of the board in 1999. See KSE, Securities Listing Regulations, art. 48-5 (as amended Feb. 14, 1998). Previously, only certain public enterprises and financial institutions were required to have outside directors. See Public Enterprise Management Structure Improvement and Privatization Act, Law No. 5379 of 1997 (as amended Law No. 5690 of 1999), art. 5 Public Enterprise Management Structure Improvement and Privatization Act, Law No. 5379 of 1997 (as amended Law No. 5690 of 1999), art. 5

SANG-JANG-HYUP 7 (1998).

19 See Hyo-sang Kang, supra note 16.

20 See Hyo-sang Kang et al., Gyung-young min -joo-hwa-ui gil (4): I-sa¬hwoe-neun “Yes”-man-ha-neun guh-soo-gi [The Road to Management Democ¬racy (4): Board of Directors Are a Rubber Stamp that Only Says “Yes”], CHOSUN ILBO, May 14, 1996

failure of directors to perform their duties in an objective and fidu¬cial manner had especially acute consequences under the Korean legal system, as directors in Korean corporations have a heightened responsibility due to their double function as officers. 21 Auditors thus also failed to act as internal watchdogs monitoring the man¬agerial decisions made by the board. 22 Corporate decisions reflect¬ed the will of the principal shareholders. In the end, all of the cen¬tral internal controls that were established under the KCC to monitor and manage corporate decision-making failed to operate.

2.2. Marginalized Nonprincipal Shareholders

Nonprincipal shareholders, on the other hand, played a marginal role in corporate affairs. Not only did they lack influence, but they also generally remained passive actors. First, a barrage of regulato¬ry obstacles thwarted nonprincipal shareholders from more active participation in corporate policy. Most of the minimum holding re¬quirements for exercising various shareholder rights were set at the prohibitively high level of five percent of the total issued stock, which effectively froze out many shareholders from participating in corporate affairs.23

With listed companies averaging 62.3 billion won (U.S. $52 million) in capital stock in 1997, a five percent holding requirement,

21 See Hee-chul Chung, Summary, supra note 6, at 49, 58

22 See KCC art. 412

23 See Chul-song Lee, So-soo -joo -joo-gwon-ui shil-hyo-sung gum-to [Review of the Efectiveness of Minority Shareholder Rights], 35 SANG-JANG-HYUP 7 (1997).

for instance, meant that interested stockholders would have to amass over 3.1 billion won (U.S. $2.6 million) in shares to exercise their shareholder rights.24 This threshold requirement, therefore, served as an insurmountable obstacle for most small investors. Shareholder rights were seldom, if ever, exercised.25 One indicator of the difficulties shareholders experienced in taking action is that, until recently, meaningful shareholder litigation never existed in Korea.26 Institutional investors, on the other hand, who could have played a pivotal role, could not participate in corporate affairs be¬cause they were limited to shadow voting for customer accounts.27

One of the main reasons why policy makers kept the minimum holding requirements so high was because they wished to protect management.28 Policy makers believed that because management needed to make swift and decisive judgments, it could not be bur¬dened by outside pressures such as shareholders. Concerns also existed that if minimum holding requirements were lowered, they would be abused by bad faith shareholders, and companies would be immobilized by an onslaught of litigation from disgruntled

24 See KOREA LISTED CO. ASS’N, SANG-JANG-HWOE-SA-YON-GAM 1998

[LISTED COMPANIES ALMANAC 1998], 1998, at 53. All foreign exchange calcu¬lations in this Article are calculated at U.S. $1 = 1200 won. This calculation was made on a par value basis

25 See infra Section 3.3.

26 See Dong-yoon Chung, Too -ja -ja-bo-ho-reul wui-han so-song -jae-do-ae gwan-han yon-goo [Research Paper on Litigation Procedures to Protect Inves¬tors], 35 SANG-JANG-HYUP 27 (1997)

27 See Securities Investment Trust Business Act, supra note 1, arts. 25, 25-2

28 See Chul-song Lee, supra note 23. Management was also granted protec¬tion as a means to promote the newly established financial market because many companies were reluctant to list their shares on the market out of fear they would lose control. See Joon Park, Symposium: Capital Market and Financial Service in the Pacific Rim: Prospect for Harmonization, 28 LAW & POL’Y INT’L BUS. 893 (1997). See generally JUNG-RYUM KIM, HAN-GOOK-GYUNG-JAE-JUNG¬CHEK 30-NYUN-SA [30 YEARS OF KOREAN ECONOMIC HISTORY] 278-84 (1995)

(discussing the history of policies implemented to induce Korean companies to go public).

shareholders. 29 Some also claimed that racketeers would acquire shares and threaten to cause trouble at shareholders’ meetings, ex¬torting payoffs in return for their cooperation. The recent increase in directors’ liability insurance has been cited as another negative aspect and added expense of the new shareholding requirements.30

Given the Korean context, however, these arguments remain unpersuasive. First, natural barriers to litigation deter already no n¬litigious Koreans. Litigation is time-consuming, expensive, and in¬volves public exposure. Furthermore, Korea does not allow class action suits.31 The modified minimum holding threshold still re¬quires a substantial sum of shares. With the average total market value of Korean listed companies at approximately 228 billion won (U.S. $190 million), one percent of the total shares would require shareholders with 2.28 billion won (U. S. $1.9 million) worth of stock to unite forces.32

Unlike Japan, the activity of racketeers has been marginal at best.33 Despite the recently lowered Securities Exchange Act (“SEA”) threshold, there have been only a few reported shareholder derivative suits, all of which have occurred since 1997.34 The con¬cerns about extortionist litigation have not materialized, and if any concerns still exist regarding extortion-oriented or bad faith litiga¬tion, many observers have pointed out that the courts can prevent such actions from taking place.35

29 See generally Korea Center for Free Enterprises (visited Sept. 1, 1999) <http://www.cfe.org> (discussing more in depth the potential problems of en¬hancing shareholder rights in Korea).

30 See Joanna Slater, Running for Cover: Directors Seek Insurance Against Liability, FAR E. ECON. REV., Feb. 4, 1999, at 47 (discussing the increase to ap¬proximately 100 new policies in 1998 from practically none in 1997).

31 See Dong-yoon Chung, supra note 13 (discussing the need for Korea to adopt the U.S. class action system or the German Verbandsklage system). A draft law for class actions in securities-related cases has been presented to the National Assembly, but has yet to be adopted. See The National Assembly of the Republic of Korea (visited Nov. 1, 1999) <http://www.assembly.go.kr>.

32 See KSE, 368 Joo-shik [Stock] 12, Apr. 1999.

33 See Edward Lincoln, Behind the Chrysanthemum Curtain, ASIAN WALL ST. J., Nov. 19, 1997, at 12

34 Korea First Bank, Korea Telecom, and Samsung Electronics are the only recent examples. See infra Sections 4.3, 4.4

35 See Ki-won Choi, IMF ui geuk-bok-eul wui-han sang-bup-gae -jung bang¬hyang (I) [How the Korean Commercial Code Should Be Amended to Overcome

When one weighs the consequences of an overprotective and unbridled management that lacks accountability versus the alleged need for speedy and decisive decision making, it appears that the government’s overall policy intentions over the years have outlived their initial purpose.

Korean shareholders were also generally not interested in par¬ticipating in corporate governance. Most shareholders, in fact, did not even realize that they had rights.36 The primary focus for Kore¬an shareholders was short-term gains rather than long-term invest¬ment.37 This short-term investment strategy consequently led to lit¬tle loyalty or interest in the affairs of corporate management.38

Nonprincipal shareholders, therefore, lacked the ability and in¬terest to participate in corporate affairs. As testimony to the margi¬nal role of shareholders, shareholders’ meetings became symbolic events held according to predetermined scripts that merely rubber¬stamped major board decisions.39 In fact, the overall lack of pro¬tection for the interests of nonprincipal shareholders was considered to be one of the major barriers to foreign investment.40

2.3. The Vulnerability of the Korean Corporate Paradigm: The Case of the Chaebols

The results of this lapse in corporate regulation is best illustrat¬ed by the chaebol, or family-owned conglomerates, that maintain an

the IMF Situation (I) ], L. TIMES (Seoul), Apr. 16, 1998, at 14

36 See Scourge of the Chaebol, ECONOMIST, Mar. 27, 1999, at 68.

37 For instance, the average length of ownership for individual investors was 1.2 months between January and July of 1999, 1.9 months in 1998, and 4.1 months in 1997. See KSE Press Release, Aug. 21, 1999 (on file with author).

38 See infra Section 3.8 for further discussion on how the low dividend poli¬cy played an important role in the short-term investment strategy of most Korean shareholders.

39 On the ineffectual nature of Korean shareholders’ meetings, see ROGER L.

JANELLI & DAWNHEE YIM, MAKING CAPITALISM: THE SOCIAL AND CULTURAL CONSTRUCTION OF A SOUTH KOREAN CONGLOMERATE (Stanford Univ. Press

1993)

40 See Soo-geun Oh, supra note 15.

overwhelming position in the Korean economy.41 First, as principal shareholders, the chieftains of Korea’s chaebol conglomerates took full advantage of the lack of internal controls and checks and bal¬ances in Korean corporations. They dominated entire conglome r¬ates and controlled dozens of subsidiaries and related companies while avoiding any accountability. 42

These principal shareholders of the chaebol conglomerates us u¬ally held positions as “Chairmen,” yet they would officially register themselves as directors in only the major corporations within the conglomerate.43 This overall structure allowed chieftains to mini¬mize their legal responsibility.44 Chairmen, furthermore, reigned over conglomerates with only a marginal portion of the outstanding shares, often amounting to less than three percent.45 Companies within a conglomerate were instead held together through an inter¬locking web of cross shareholding ownership between related and sister companies.46 They avoided assuming legally binding posi

41 See Mufson, supra note 10. The financial sector, which saw the collapse of such firms as Koryo Securities, Dongsuh Securities, Daedong Bank, Dongnam Bank, Kyunggi Bank, Chungchung Bank, Korea First Bank, and Seoul Bank, also serves as a prime example of the failed Korean corporate paradigm. See Schu¬man, Piling On, supra note 12

42 See Chan-hyung Chung, supra note 14

43 None of the leading chaebols has been ever controlled by a woman.

44 See Seung-wook Chung, Directors, supra note 42.

45 See KSE Press Release, Sept. 16, 1999 (on file with author). See gener¬ally Hee-kab Kang, Woo-ri-na-ra-ui Gi-up -ji-bae-goo -jo-ui ip-bup-ron -juk gum¬to [Review of the Legislative Theory Behind Korea’s Corporate Governance] 39 SANG-JANG-HYUP 20, 28 (1999). To curb their influence, one observer has sug¬gested limiting the voting rights of these principal shareholders. See Hee-chul Chung, Problems, supra note 6, at 12-13.

46 In the case of the 10 largest chaebols, the principal stake of chaebol chairmen has in fact increased from 26.63% to 34.6% as a result of cross owner¬ship and other family interests since the 1997 financial crisis. See KSE Press Release, supra note 45

tions and limited their personal investment risk while, at the same time, being the principal of the conglomerate.

Chairmen dominated directors and auditors. Nonprincipal shareholders, in turn, did not provide any monitoring pressure. Un¬like the corporate governance systems in Japan or continental Europe, financial intermediaries failed to offer any supervisory dis¬cipline.47 The chance of being held accountable became remote, and investment risk exposure was minimal. Chaebol chairmen naturally gravitated to a business strategy that emphasized diversifi¬cation, size, and market share over profitability and shareholder value.48 From this perspective, the interests of the entire chaebol conglomerate were placed above the well-being of individual cor¬porations and their respective shareholders. Dividends, for instance, were kept to a minimum.

In the initial stages, the chaebol model arguably held some ad¬vantages, such as efficient and speedy decision-making.49 Yet any management system that operates without adequate supervision or monitoring cannot remain internationally competitive. The longer such a system persists and the larger a company becomes, the greater will be the agency costs and the subsequent decline in effi¬ciency. The chaebol’s corporate structure exemplified these char¬acteristics.

One person dominated all the companies in an entire con¬glomerate without any effective checks or balances or accountabil¬ity. This management structure eventually became plagued with in¬efficiencies and irregularities. Chaebols often became

N.Y. TIMES, Sept. 21, 1999. See generally Curtis J. Milhaupt, Property Rights in Firms, 84 VA. L. REV. 1145, 1162-63 (1998).

47 See Coffee, supra note 4.

48 This overall corporate ownership structure can be traced to Korea’s indus¬trial policy. In an effort to industrialize the economy through chaebol conglom¬erates, Korean policymakers believed that Korean corporations should be pro¬tected. See Namju Cho, Korea Takes New Step to Spur Mergers, ASIAN WALL ST. J., Mar. 20, 1997, at 1 (calling Korean corporations “often-coddled”) [herein¬after Namju Cho, Korea Takes New Step]. But see The Apologist: The World Blames South Korea’s Huge Conglomerates for the Country’s Economic Melt¬down -Bae Ie-Dong Has the Thankless Task of Defending Them, ECONOMIST , Aug. 29, 1998, at 62 (profiling an economist for the chaebol’s lobbying associa¬tion who argues that the chaebol’s excessive borrowing and emphasis on market share were necessary) [hereinafter The Apologist].

49 See Seung-min Yoo, supra note 12, at 13-15 (providing a comparison of the various asserted strengths and weaknesses of the chaebol’s concentrated management style).

nonspecialized, bloated behemoths that were largely sustained by debt.50 At their worst, the conglomerate culture became conducive to illicit activities adverse to the interests of individual corporations and their respective shareholders. Funds from profitable companies were shifted to support new and weaker companies through transfer pricing and cross guarantees.51 More egregious examples included the expropriation of company funds, the creation of slush funds, and self-dealing by the principal shareholders.52 To conceal these prac¬tices from shareholders and regulators, opaqueness instead of trans¬parency became the standard practice of choice.53 As chaebols be¬came uncompetitive and vulnerable to outside shocks, the system began to unravel gradually, outliving most of the merits it once had.

The failure of corporate regulation, therefore, ultimately con¬tributed to the spectacular failures of such mainstay conglomerates as Daewoo, Hanbo, Kia, and Daenong. 54 Given the dominant posi¬tion of the chaebol, their failures had multiple repercussions throughout the Korean economy and helped precipitate the severity of the 1997 financial crisis.

50 See The Apologist, supra note 48 (discussing how the chaebols started going bankrupt as they became unable to pay interest charges on skyrocketing debts out of cash flow). The defunct Hanbo Steel was one of the most over¬leveraged companies in Korea before it collapsed, having amassed five trillion won in debt, over 22 times its equity. See Schuman, Tangled Web, supra note 41.

51 See infra Section 4.4.

52 See Mufson, supra note 10

53 See Soo-geun Oh, supra note 15, at 73-74.

54 Among the top 30 major chaebol conglomerates, 11 have been taken over, have filed for bankruptcy, or are undergoing workout proceedings. The failed chaebols, along with their old rankings in parentheses, include Daewoo (2nd), Kia (8th), Halla (12th), Hanbo (14th), Jinro (19th), New Core (25th), Sammi (26th), and Dainong (34th). See Dong-han Lee, Shil -pae yon-gu: 2 sae chong¬soo dok-dan-ae ‘in-ui jang-mak’ kka -ji [Study of Failure: From the Autocracy of Second Generation Chieftains to Being Sheltered by ‘Curtains of People’],

CHOSUN ILBO, Apr. 19, 1999, at 13.

2000] KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AMENDMENTS 287

3. THE NEW KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE

To correct these various structural problems, the KCC was amended three times in the past four years. The 1995 amendments came after more than ten years of review and became effective on October 1, 1996. The preamble of the 1995 KCC provides that one of the primary purposes of the revisions was to “enhance the inter¬national competitiveness of Korean companies.”55 The major focus of the 1998 amendments was to address the failures that were ex¬posed during the financial crisis.56 The 1998 amendments included provisions to simplify the mergers and acquisitions process, in¬crease the accountability of de facto directors, and strengthen mi¬nority shareholder rights. The 1999 amendments, however, includ¬ed regulations concerning stock options and audit committees. The various amendments that occurred in 1995, 1998, and 1999 will be reviewed by subject matter, with an emphasis on changes affecting corporate governance.

3.1. Directors

One of the main objectives of revising the KCC was to make di¬rectors more accountable. Under the previous legal regime, direc¬tors had an obligation to their company based on a general standard called the “duty of diligence as a good custodian (sun-lyang-han¬gwan-li -ja-ui -ju-ui-ui-mu),” which was similar to a combination of the duty of good faith and fair dealing.57 This general standard was not based on a provision in the Commercial Code, but applied to corporate directors indirectly through reference to Article 681 of the Civil Code.58 Directors, in turn, neglected their roles as good cus¬todians or fiduciaries.59 To heighten awareness of the fundamental responsibility that directors owe to their corporations, an explicit fi¬duciary duty has now been imposed upon directors.60 Under this provision, directors must fulfill their obligations in a fiduciary man

55 1995 KCC preamble.

56 See 1998 KCC preamble.

57 Ki-won Choi, supra note 1. Some believe that, other than symbolically, the fiduciary duty and the general due diligence standards are not significantly distinguishable, and propose instead that Korea follow the German model, plac¬ing the burden of proof on directors to properly carry out their duties. See id.

58 See KCC art. 1 (providing that the Civil Code applies when a matter is not covered by the KCC).

59 See infra Section 4 for various examples.

60 See 1998 KCC art. 382-3.

ner on behalf of the company as provided by the law, as well as by the articles of incorporation.61

Secondly, the new KCC requires directors to act more vigilantly in protecting the interests of their company. Directors now have a duty to immediately report to the company’s statutory auditor any facts they learn that may “significantly injure” the company. 62 This provision affirmatively forces directors to be more attentive in pro¬tecting the interests of shareholders. The potential effectiveness of this new duty, however, will depend on how the courts interpret the term “significant injury.” (Similarly, the board of directors’ minutes must now include the names of any directors that objected to any decisions, and the reasons why they objected.63 Not only did directors rarely object to board decisions, but board minutes rarely provided any detailed information concerning any objections in the past. At the same time, companies may now reject a shareholder’s inspection request if they provide a “reason.”64 If rejected, the shareholder must obtain court approval for an inspection, placing the burden on the shareholder, rather than the company.)

Thirdly, another significant amendment to the KCC is that prin¬cipal shareholders now may be considered to have the same respon¬sibilities and liabilities as directors under certain circumstances. Under the old regulatory framework, it was extremely difficult to establish liability against principal shareholders.65 One would have to either demonstrate that the principal shareholders were de facto directors or pierce the corporate veil -both challenging tasks, given that the party making such an assertion has the burden of proof. 66

The new KCC therefore provides that persons who “use their in¬fluence to direct or participate in the corporate affairs of directors” can be held jointly and severally liable with the other directors of a company.67 Persons who hold titles such as “honorary chairman,” “chairman,” “president,” “vice-president,” or conduct corporate af

61 See id.

62 1995 KCC art. 412-2.

63 See 1999 KCC art. 391-3. Creditors can no longer inspect board minutes. See id. art. 396.

64 See id. art. 391-3

65 See Seung-wook Chung, Shareholders, supra note 42.

66 See Seung-wook Chung, Directors, supra note 42, at 96-97

67 1998 KCC art. 401-2.

2000] KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AMENDMENTS 289

fairs under the pretext of such titles, in particular, will be deemed to be directors even if they are not registered directors.68 The principal shareholders who have dominated corporate decision-making can no longer avoid managerial liability merely by not registering as di¬rectors. This new provision makes it substantially easier to find principal shareholders accountable as directors.69 They will be con¬sidered the same as other directors with the same duties and respon¬sibilities. As a result, many company chieftans are finally register¬ing as directors.70

The new KCC amendments also seek to accommodate the inter¬ests of small companies. First, corporations having less than 500 million won (U.S. $418,000) in paid-in capital, for example, do not have an obligation to elect a minimum of three directors.71 This new provision allows small corporations to avoid the unnecessary burden of electing ghost directors who only lend their name during the process of incorporation but do nothing else, a common practice in the past.72 If a small corporation elects only one director, all oc¬casions where the KCC requires approval from the board of direc¬tors will require instead approval from the shareholders.73

Finally, to enhance the efficiency of the board of directors, sev¬eral changes have been made. The entire board may now delegate certain functions to a subcommittee of directors.74 Those functions that cannot be delegated include such matters as the election or ter¬mination of the representative director and the proposal of issues that require shareholder approval. Furthermore, unless provided otherwise in the articles of incorporation, directors may now par

68 See id. art. 401-2, para. 1, subpara. 3.

69 Minority shareholders of Korea Telecom recently brought a case against the government claiming that the government should be responsible under this provision because it in fact dictated corporate affairs at Korea Telecom. See In¬soon Kim, Han-gook-tong-shin so-aek -joo -joo, jung-boo-ae joo -joo-dae -pyo-so¬song [Korea Telecom Minority Shareholders Bring a Shareholder Derivative Ac¬tion Against the Government], MAEIL BUS. NEWS (Seoul), Apr. 12, 1999.

70 See Jong-young Kim, Geu-rup-hwoe -jang -jae pye -ji … joo-ryuk-sa gyung-young jip -joong [Abolishing of the Conglomerate Chairman System … Concentrating Management of Main Companies], MAEIL BUS. NEWS, Feb. 28, 1998.

71 See 1998 KCC art. 383.

72 For a critical view of this amendment, see Ki-won Choi, supra note 35.

73 See 1998 KCC art. 383, para. 4.

74 See 1999 KCC art. 393-2.

ticipate in board meetings through simultaneous audiovisual elec¬tronic transmission.75

3.2. Auditors and Audit Committees

One of the most dubious positions in a Korean corporation be¬longs to that of statutory auditors.76 Auditors were established as internal institutions to monitor corporate affairs and the decision making of directors on behalf of shareholders,77 yet they were un¬able to fulfill their function. The recent amendments seek to strengthen the authority of auditors so they can effectively act as internal watchdogs, as intended under the Commercial Code. For instance, companies can now establish an audit committee to re¬place the functions of the auditor.78

First, to enhance their standing, auditors will receive protection from unjust termination.79 Auditors commonly feared retaliatory discharge if they raised any challenges against management in the interests of the corporation or its shareholders. To allay these con¬cerns, auditors now have a guaranteed opportunity to inform all shareholders of the circumstances of their termination.

Auditors also have been empowered with the right to convene a shareholders’ meeting. 80 In the past, only the board of directors or shareholders who met a high holding requirement could call a shareholders’ meeting. Auditors, especially outside auditors who are required for large companies, have gained tremendous authority

75 See id. art. 391.

76 See Chan-hyung Chung, supra note 14, at 14-15

JANG-HYUP 42 (1998).

77 See KCC art. 412

See 1999 KCC art. 415-2. See 1995 KCC art. 409-2. See id. art. 412-3.

2000] KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AMENDMENTS 291

as a result of this provision. 81 They can unilaterally call sharehold¬ers’ meetings in order to inform shareholders, take votes on contro¬versial issues, and confirm board decisions.

Finally, the term of office for auditors has been extended from two years to three years, in order to match the length of the term for directors.82 It was believed that longer terms would provide audi¬tors more job security and more independent authority.

In addition to granting these various protections, the new KCC limits the qualifications of auditors to guarantee their objectivity. An individual can no longer be both an auditor of a parent company and a director of a subsidiary company at the same time.83 Parent company directors tend to have a strong influence over the directors of a subsidiary. Absent this position, auditors of a parent company could have a conflict of interest when auditing decisions made by the parent company’s directors concerning their influence over a subsidiary’s directors. If auditors of a parent company were jointly allowed to be directors of a subsidiary, they would be forced to audit affairs relating to themselves. 84 In contrast, a person may be an auditor of both a parent and a subsidiary company, or a director of a parent company and an auditor of a subsidiary company without implicating conflict of interest concerns.

If an audit committee is established based on the terms of a company’s articles of incorporation, the committee must consist of at least three directors. 85 In electing audit committee members, the committee cannot consist of more than one-third of the following categories: (1) an inside director or a person who was an inside di¬rector within the last two years

81 See infra Section 4.4.

82 See 1995 KCC art. 410. The term of office for auditors was extended from one year to two years in 1984. See Ju-chan Sonn, Reflections, supra note 6, at 34.

83 See 1995 KCC art. 411

an-hae-sul [Explanatory Notes on Proposed Amendments to the Commercial

Code] 139 (Bupmoonsa Publishers 1995) [hereinafter Explanatory Notes].

84 See Explanatory Notes, supra note 83, at 139.

85 See 1999 KCC art. 415-2.

Furthermore, audit committee members can only be terminated by a vote of over two-thirds of the board of directors. These various re¬quirements were stipulated to ensure the independence of the audit committee.

3.3. Strengthening Shareholder Rights

Among the various amendments to the KCC, some of the most significant changes involved the new measures to strengthen the neglected rights of shareholders. The 1995 KCC, 1998 KCC, and 1999 KCC sought to make it easier for shareholders to exercise their existing rights and also sought to establish new rights on their behalf. These changes led to a seismic shift in the overall scheme of corporate regulation.

2000] KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AMENDMENTS 293 Table 1: Recent Amendments to the KCC and SEA86

Shareholder Right KCC SEA

Type 199587 199888 199789 Feb. May Jan. 200092

199890 199891

Requesting 5% 3% 1% 0.5% N/C 0.25%

termination of (0.5%) (0.25%) (0.125%)

directors &

auditors

Seeking injunctive 5% 1% 1% 0.5% N/C 0.25%

action against (0.5%) (0.25%) (0.125%)

illegal acts

Bringing share-

holder derivative

actions 5% 1% 1%

(0.5%) 0.05% 0.01 % 0.005%

Convening a special

shareholders’

meeting 5% 3% 3%

(1.5%) N/C N/C 1.5 %

(0.75%)

Compelling

production of

financial records for

inspection 5% 3% 3%

(1.5%) 1%

(0.5%) N/C 0.5%

(0.25%)

Appointing an

inspector to exami-

ne corporate affairs,

records, & finan

cial status 5% 3% 3%

(1.5%) N/C N/C 1.5 %

(0.75%)

Terminating a

liquidator 5% 3% 3%

(1.5%) 0.5%

(0.25%) N/C 0.25%

(0.125%)

Requesting cumu-

lative voting – 3 % – – – –

Making a share-

holder proposal – 3% 1%

(0.5%) N/C N/C 0.5 %

(0.25%)

Requesting

dissolution 10% 10% – – – –

86 The numbers in parentheses apply to listed or registered companies with at least 100 billion won in paid-in capital. SEA applies to shareholders with at least six months ownership. January 2000 revisions to the SEA only apply to certain securities companies with at least two trillion won in assets. N/C signifies no change.

87 KCC, as amended by Law No. 5053 of 1995 (effective Oct. 1, 1996).

88 KCC, as amended by Law No. 5591 of 1998 (effective Dec. 28, 1998, ex¬cept for the cumulative voting provision, which became effective on June 28, 1998).

89 SEA, as amended by Law No. 5254 of 1997 (effective Apr. 1, 1997).

90 SEA, as amended by Law No. 5521 of 1998 (effective Apr. 1, 1998).

91 SEA, as amended by Law No. 5539 of 1998 (effective May 25, 1998).

92 SEA, as amended by Law No. 6176 of 2000 (effective Apr. 1, 2000).

First and foremost, although the minimum holding requirements for exercising various shareholder rights remain high,93 consider¬able progress has been achieved in that these requirements were significantly lowered. Overall, the new KCC has reduced the minimum holding standards required to exercise the following rights:94 (1) requesting a court to terminate directors and auditors for improper or illegal acts in contravention of any law or the arti¬cles of incorporation, reduced from five percent to three percent

As noted above, it is now easier for shareholders to seek the termination of a director. In the past, when a director committed an “improper act,” or violated “a law or the articles of incorporation,” shareholder attempts to terminate such a director were often sty¬mied at the shareholders’ meeting due to the dominance of the prin¬cipal shareholders.102 Dissenting shareholders with only three per¬cent of the total shares can now request the termination before a

93 The holding requirements for shareholders of listed companies were first lowered at the end of 1996. See SEA, Law No. 5254 of 1997

94 This summary of percentages excludes shares that do not have voting rights, such as most preferred shares. For a summary of litigation-related inves¬tor rights, see Dong-yoon Chung, supra note 26, at 41-42.

95 See 1998 KCC art. 385.

96 See id. art. 402.

97 See id. art. 403.

98 See id. art. 366.

99 See id. art. 466. Ki-won Choi argues that since shareholder derivative suits are in fact impossible without the right to inspect financial records that these two rights should have the same requirement of one percent. See Ki-won Choi, supra note 35.

100 See 1998 KCC art. 467.

101 See id. art. 539.

102 Id. art. 385.

2000] KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AMENDMENTS 295

competent court after such a shareholders’ meeting. This provides an important means by which to hold directors more accountable, especially those protected by the dominant shareholder.

In the case of the shareholder derivative action, the new law not only lowered the holding requirement, but also added a critical feature.103 Under the new law, the one percent holding requirement for bringing a derivative action only has to be met when the action commences and need not be maintained for the duration of the case. This change greatly facilitates the ability of small investors to sus¬tain derivative actions, especially because most investors in Korea do not hold onto their shares for extended periods.104 Overall, the lower minimum ownership requirements mark an important step in empowering shareholders to oversee the actions of directors. As a result, the number of shareholder actions has risen significantly.105

In addition to lowering the various holding requirements, both the 1998 and 1999 amendments established several new sharehold¬ers’ rights. First, as provided in the articles of incorporation, share¬holders can now execute their votes in writing without actually at¬tending the shareholders’ meeting. 106 This makes it substantially easier for shareholders to exercise their rights. Second, sharehold¬ers can request cumulative voting when electing directors.107 Shareholders with at least three percent of the total shares can re¬quest cumulative voting when more than two directors are elected. Companies must accept such a request unless they have added a provision in their articles of incorporation to exclude it. Amending the articles of incorporation requires a special majority vote at a shareholders’ meeting, which may be a considerable burden. 108

One problem with this provision is that, unlike the other provi¬sions of the 1998 KCC, it did not become effective until June 28,

103 See id. art. 403, para. 5.

104 See KSE Press Release, supra note 37.

105 See infra Section 4.

106 See 1999 KCC art. 366-3.

107 See 1998 KCC art. 382-2. One observer argues that Korea is not ready for the cumulative voting system because it will create confusion. See Ki-won Choi, supra note 35. Choi proposes instead a new system of corporate gover¬nance whereby 50% of the board would be elected as before, 25% would be elected with each shareholder’s voting rights being limited to a maximum of 3%, and the remaining 25% would be elected by large creditors. See id. For comp a¬nies with more than 10,000 workers, a representative from the workers would be elected. See id.

108 See infra note 118 and accompanying text.

1999. Any election of directors preceding that date did not have to be executed with cumulative voting, and companies were granted a chance to adopt exclusionary provisions to prohibit it. According to the Korea Stock Exchange, of the 516 listed companies with fiscal years ending in December 1998, 386 companies, or 74.8%, man¬aged to enact provisions excluding cumulative voting.109 The re¬maining 130 companies, or 26.2%, and those companies that have not adopted such exclusionary provisions by June 1999, will have to adopt cumulative voting.

Another important right created for shareholders is the right to propose items to be placed on the agenda of a shareholders’ meet¬ing .110 Interested shareholders with at least three percent of the total issued shares must first submit their proposals to the responsible di¬rector six weeks before the shareholders’ meeting. Shareholders can request that their proposal items be included along with other material and notices sent to other shareholders. The board of di¬rectors must accept a shareholder proposal thus submitted unless it contravenes a law or the articles of incorporation. 111

Those who make a shareholder proposal may then request an opportunity to explain their proposal at the shareholders’ meet¬ing .112 Companies that fail to comply with the shareholder proposal provision may be subject to a fine of up to five million won (U.S.

109 See Yoon -jae Han, 12 wol gyol-san-bup-in 75% jib -jung-tu -pyo -jae do-ip an-ki-ro [75% of Companies with Fiscal Years Ending in December Decide Not to Adopt Cumulative Voting], CHOSUN ILBO, Mar. 30, 1999

110 See 1998 KCC art. 363-2. The first reported case where a company ac¬cepted a shareholder proposal occurred on May 27, 1997, when Korea Interna¬tional Merchant Bank accepted a proposal to elect certain directors. See Sung-il Hong, So-aek joo-joo jae-an chut gwan-chul [Minority Shareholder Proposal Ac¬cepted for the First Time], JOONGANG ILBO, May 28, 1997. See generally Hong¬ryul Chun, Ju -ju -jae-an -jae-do-wa sang-jang-gi-up-ui dae-ung [The Shareholder Proposal and How Listed Companies Should Respond], 38 SANG-JANG-HYUP 69 (1998)

111 See 1998 KCC art. 363-2, para. 3.

112 See id.

2000] KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AMENDMENTS 297

$41,800).113 This vital provision grants shareholders the opportu¬nity to voice their opinions on issues of concern to them, instead of merely being limited to the agenda set by the company.

This provision is flawed, however, because it is not consistent with the procedures by which to convene a shareholders’ meeting. A company only has to give shareholders two weeks’ notice before convening a shareholders’ meeting. 114 Hence, if shareholders re¬ceive only the minimal two weeks’ notice, they will not have suffi¬cient time to submit a shareholder proposal, which requires six weeks’ advance notice. This means that the shareholder proposal provision can only be used if the shareholders themselves request a special shareholders’ meeting. Otherwise, for shareholders’ meet¬ings convened by the board of directors, shareholders can only guess when the actual meetings will be held and submit shareholder proposals six weeks in advance of that estimated date. One com¬pany has already used this loophole, rescheduling a shareholders’ meeting to avoid including a shareholder proposal made by several foreign funds.115

3.4. Mergers

Another important reason for amending the KCC was to ove r¬haul the regulations concerning mergers. As testimony to the sig¬nificance of mergers, the merger provisions, originally part of “Section 10 Dissolutions” under the old KCC, were moved to a newly created section specifically entitled “Section 10 Mergers” in the 1998 KCC. From one perspective, a more active mergers and acquisitions market was viewed as a means of strengthening corpo¬rate governance. 116 The lack of such external discipline was one reason why principal shareholders could maintain low share owne r¬ship and minimal risk exposure while dominating corporate affairs. The new provisions were also considered a means to facilitate cor¬porate restructuring efforts. Overall, the amendments of the merger section sought to streamline the merger procedures, enhance the

113 See id. art. 635, para. 1, subpara. 19-3.

114 See KCC art. 363.

115 See Jin-gun Chung, Mi-gook-gye fund, Nong-shim-ae aek-myun-boon-hal yo-goo [American Fund Requests Stock Split from Nongshim], MAEIL BUS. NEWS, Aug. 24, 1998.

116 See Namju Cho, Korea Takes New Step, supra note 48.

protection of shareholders, and assure adequate protection for man

agement. 117

3.4.1. Streamlining Merger Procedures

Various procedural modifications were made to facilitate the merger process. First, the special majority voting procedure re¬quired for special resolutions, such as mergers or other major cor¬porate changes, was modified. 118 Many public companies had trou¬ble meeting the quorum requirement for special resolutions, which called for attendance at the shareholders’ meeting by the sharehold¬ers of at least one-half of all shares entitled to vote.119 The special majority voting procedure now provides that a merger may be ap¬proved with just a two-thirds vote of the shareholders who attend the shareholders’ meeting. To ensure some degree of represent a¬tiveness, this two-thirds vote must consist of at least one-third of the total shares entitled to vote. Thus, the original mandatory quorum requirement for voting on a special resolution was replaced with a simpler “voting quorum.”

Another change to the new merger regulations allows compani¬es to dispense with the final reporting requirements to sharehold¬ers.120 Under the previous provisions, after a merger was approved, but before the final merger registration, the board of directors had to prepare a final report to shareholders at a special shareholders’

117 See Dong-yun Chung, Hwoe-sa-ui hap-byung -jul-cha-ui gan-so-hwa-wa joo -joo-ui bo-ho [The Simplification of Merger Procedures and the Protection of Shareholders], Public Hearing on the Amendments to the Commercial Code, Ministry of Justice, Apr. 1, 1998, at 11. This shareholder proposal right existed for listed companies under the Securities Exchange Law and was first exercised by shareholders of Korea International Merchant Bank in April 1997. See Gwang -jin Oh, Han-woi -jong-geum no -jo geum -yung-gwon chut joo -joo -jae-an¬gwon heng-sa [Korea International Merchant Bank Labor First to Exercise Shareholder Proposal Right in Financial Industry], KOREA ECON. DAILY, Apr. 15, 1997.

118 See 1995 KCC art. 434. Previously, the quorum requirement for “special resolutions” called for the attendance of shareholders representing at least one¬half of the total voting shares and a two-thirds approval among them. Because this quorum normally could not be met, unvoted shares that were deposited with the Korean Deposit Agency would be counted through shadow voting toward the quorum requirement. See SEA art. 174-6

119 Once the quorum is met, special resolutions require the approval of at least two-thirds of the total shares actually attending the shareholders’ meeting. See KCC art. 434.

120 See 1995 KCC art. 526

2000] KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AMENDMENTS 299

meeting regarding all matters relating to the proposed merger. 121 The drafters of the 1995 KCC believed that calling a shareholders’ meeting solely for this purpose was unnecessary, especially because shareholders would have already approved the merger, and the merger could not be undone or changed at that time.122 Therefore, under the new procedures, the drafters provided that the company may instead disclose any information regarding the merger accord¬ing to the public notice requirements in the company’s articles of incorporation. 123

From another perspective, new mergers and acquisitions regu¬lations were also needed to help desperate companies restructure and attract capital following the credit crunch of the financial crisis. Many companies at the time sought to merge failing or weaker sub¬sidiaries with sister companies. One way to facilitate corporate re¬structuring was the adoption of a short-form merger procedure and a small-scale merger procedure.

Established in 1995, the short-form merger procedure was fur¬ther modified under the 1998 KCC.124 Certain companies being ac¬quired can use the short-form merger procedure to substitute the mandatory shareholder approval process with the mere acceptance of the board of directors. The short-form merger can be used where the acquiring company purchases more than ninety percent of the target company’s stock or if all of the target company’s sharehold¬ers agree to adopt the procedure.125 Short-form mergers, therefore, allow companies to dispense with the requirement of convening a separate shareholders’ meeting for approval. Subsidiaries con¬trolled by parent companies, for instance, can be absorbed in a sim¬plified manner.

The new KCC also introduced a small-scale merger procedure so that large acquiring companies could purchase smaller compani¬es more easily. According to Article 527-3, a large acquiring com¬pany can use the small-scale merger when it issues less than five

121 See Explanatory Notes, supra note 83, at 195.

122 See id. at 196.

123 See KCC art. 289.

124 See 1995 KCC art. 522

125 See 1998 KCC art. 527-2. Under the old article 522 of the 1995 KCC, when the short-form merger procedure was first established, the acquiring com¬pany had to acquire 100% of the target company’s shares or receive an approval by all of the target company’s shareholders.

percent of its total shares to purchase a small company.126 In small¬scale mergers, the large acquiring company does not have to obtain shareholder approval through a separate shareholders’ meeting. Such a meeting was deemed unnecessary because, given the rela¬tively small size of the purchase, the acquisition would not affect the company substantially.127

Finally, to accelerate the merger process, two approval deadli¬nes were shortened. First, the time period allowed for creditors to object to mergers has been reduced from a minimum of two months to a minimum of one month.128 Second, the new amendments re¬duce the time needed to merge stock from three months to one month.129

3.4.2. Protecting Minority Shareholders’ Interests

While the new KCC simplified various merger procedures to facilitate the corporate restructuring process, it also sought to guar¬antee that this general deregulation did not infringe on the interests of shareholders.130 Therefore, various shareholder rights and disclo¬sure requirements were concomitantly strengthened to protect shareholders.

First, under the 1998 KCC, various documents must be made available for inspection at the company’s headquarters. During the period extending from two weeks before the convening of the shareholders’ meeting to approve the merger, to six months after the actual merger, the following documents must be made available to shareholders : the merger agreement, the final balance sheets and profit and loss statements of the respective companies, and a docu¬ment explaining the allocation of shares to the target company’s

shareholders. 13 1

126 See 1998 KCC art. 527-3.

127 Recent examples of small-scale mergers have involved Kangwon Indus¬tries, Tong Yang Cement, Orion Electric, Han Il E Wha, and Hyundai Engineer¬ing and Construction merging subsidiary or related companies.

128 See 1998 KCC art. 527-5.

129 See 1995 KCC art. 440.

130 For a discussion on how minority shareholders need further protection, see Hyun-yoon Shin, Sang-bup-sang gi-up-gyul-hap-ui sa -jun-tong -jae-wa moon -jae -jum [The Prior Controls, and Their Problems, in Corporate Consoli¬dation under the Commercial Code], 18 COM. L. REV. 51 (1999).

131 See 1998 KCC art. 522-2.

2000] KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AMENDMENTS 301

Subsequently, the board of directors must provide additional post-merger disclosure. For a period of six months after the merger, the directors must also provide information concerning the status of objecting creditors, the total assets and liabilities assumed from the target company, the date of the merger, and other information relat¬ed to the merger.132 This information must be made available to shareholders for inspection at the company’s headquarters.

In the case of short-form mergers, the target company’s share¬holders must be notified within two weeks that a merger is pro¬ceeding without a shareholders’ meeting. If they desire, the target company’s shareholders can, of course, waive this notice require¬ment.133 The notice may be given through the public notice process or through direct notice to individual shareholders.

Finally, to use the small-scale merger procedure, the large ac¬quiring company must state in the merger agreement that it did not convene a formal shareholders’ meeting. The large acquiring com¬pany must also alert shareholders to the acquired company’s name, location of its headquarters, and the date of the merger through ei¬ther a public notice or individual notification. 134 However, a large acquiring company cannot use the small-scale merger procedure if it has to pay more than two percent of its net assets to purchase the small target company’s shares.135 Shareowners who own more than twenty percent of the total shares can also demand that the acquir¬ing company use the normal merger procedure instead of the small¬scale procedure. 136 Furthermore, shareholders who object to the small-scale merger may request appraisal rights. 137

3.4.3. Accommodating Management Concerns

The simplification of the mergers procedures also raised con¬cerns among companies about the threats of hostile takeovers.138 In response to these concerns, anyone that acquires more than ten per¬cent of the issued stock of another company must, in due course,

132 See id. art. 527-6.

133 See id. art. 527-2.

134 See id. art. 527-3.

135 See id. para. 1.

136 See id. para. 4.

137 See id. para. 5.

138 See Hup Choi, Woe-gook-in juk-dae -juk M&A sa-shil-sang shil-hyun uh¬ryup-da [Actually Dificult for Foreign Hostile M&As to Occur], CHOSUN ILBO, Feb. 9, 1998.

notify that company of their new ownership position to provide suf¬ficient notice to that company.139 This ten percent disclosure rule was enacted to give fair warning so that threatened companies would have an opportunity to defend themselves. In particular, the effectiveness of this rule will depend on whether acquisitions by related and interested shareholders will be effectively combined when calculating the ten percent threshold to prevent circumvention.

As an ultimate means of protection, lawmakers granted comp a¬nies the ability to restrict the transfer of shares. 140 A company can require stockholders to obtain the board of directors’ approval be¬fore they sell their shares. This restriction was added so that closed corporations could maintain “mutual trust between shareholders” by preventing unwanted shareholder participation. 141 It is therefore only supposed to apply to closed corporations and not to listed or public corporations.142 This restriction only applies to newly issued shares and must be stated in the articles of incorporation

3.5. Corporate Spinofs

In conjunction with the new mergers regulations, for the first time corporations can spin off divisions into other corporations. An entire section devoted to corporate spinoffs was added to the 1998 amendments of the KCC under Section 11 immediately following the new section on mergers. 144 These spinoff procedures offer another means to assist companies in their restructuring efforts. In particular, larger companies that needed to specialize their opera

139 See 1995 KCC art. 342-3. A similar five percent rule already exists under SEA art. 200-2.

140 See 1995 KCC art. 335.

141 Explanatory Notes, supra note 83, at 84.

142 See id. at 85-86. Listed companies are excluded from this restriction un¬der the SEA.

143 In addition, if a company has decided to place this type of transfer re¬striction on a stock, convertible bond, or bond with warrant, then it must be in¬cluded in the various documents related to such securities instruments. Such documents include the offer statements (1995 KCC arts. 302, 514, 516-4), the in¬strument certificates (1995 KCC arts. 356, 514, 516-4), and the securities instru¬ment holder lists (1995 KCC arts. 514, 516-4). The information concerning the restriction must be registered (1995 KCC art. 317).

144 See 1998 KCC sec. 11.

2000] KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AMENDMENTS 303

tions or that wanted to shed corporate divisions welcomed the new procedures. 145

The new section on spinoffs broadly divides spinoffs into “Standard Spinoffs” and “Spinoff Mergers.”146 A Standard Spinoff involves a single company dividing into several different companies. Spinoff Mergers proceed one step further, occurring when a single company divides into several different companies and then one or more of these new companies simultaneously merge into other pre¬existing companies. Short-form spinoff mergers and small-scale spinoff mergers are also possible.147 In either case, the original company may or may not continue to exist, and only stock corpora¬tions can engage in spinoffs. 148

Numerous restrictions have been established to protect interest¬ed parties such as shareholders and creditors during the spinoff pro¬cess. First, shareholders must approve spinoffs with the same spe¬cial majority vote required for mergers.149 Shareholders who object to Spinoff Mergers can furthermore request appraisal rights.150 While dissenting shareholders of Standard Spinoffs do not have ap¬praisal rights, a provision provides that if the “burden of the share¬holders” increases as a result of a Standard Spinoff or Spinoff Merger, then approval from all the shareholders is required.151 Creditors also have considerable rights because they can block companies from engaging in Standard Spinoffs or Spinoff Merg

152

ers.

Companies that remain in existence after a spinoff or companies established as a result of a spinoff are jointly and severally liable for all the debts of the company from which they originated.153 This obligation was created to deter firms from abusing the spinoff pro

145 See Bok-ki Hong, Sang-bup-ae it-suh-suh Hwoe-sa-ui boon-hal-ae gwan¬han gyu -jung-ui do-ip-gum-to [Considering the Adoption of Regulations on Cor¬porate Spinofs in the Commercial Code], 17 COM. L. REV. 343 (1998)

SOO SHIN ET AL., KOREA LISTED CO. ASS’N, HWOE-SA-BOON-HAL-UI JAE-DO¬WHA-AE GWAN-HAN YON-GOO [RESEARCH STUDY ON THE REGULATION OF CORPORATE SPINOFFS] (Dec. 1995).

146 1998 KCC art. 530-2.

See 1999 KCC art. 530-11. See 1998 KCC art. 530-4. See id. art. 530-3.

See id. arts. 530-11, 522-3. Id. art. 530-3.

See id. arts. 530-9, 530-11. See id. art. 530-9.

cedure. Otherwise, abusive dominant shareholders could, for in¬stance, siphon assets to a spinoff company and leave the original company as a shell with all the liabilities.

In a Standard Spinoff, if shareholders of the original company approve of the spinoff by a special majority vote, the liabilities of the newly established spinoff company could be limited to the amount that the original firm invests into it.154 Similarly, for Spinoff Mergers, the liability could be limited to the amount that the original firm invests into the preexisting company that merges with the spinoff. In both Standard Spinoffs and Spinoff Mergers, if the original company continues to exist after the spinoff, then it will only be responsible for the liability not assumed by the new spinoff. Hanwha Living and Creative Corporation became the first spinoff of a listed company on July 1, 1999, when it divided into two com

panies. 155

3.6. The Expansion of Appraisal Rights

Dissenting shareholders can now claim appraisal rights under a variety of new circumstances. 156 The KCC provides that appraisal rights will be offered to shareholders in the following situations: (1) if a shareholder disagrees with a merger proposal or a signifi¬cant sale or purchase of business operations

In the first two cases, where a shareholder disagrees with a merger or a significant sale or purchase of business operations, or with a spinoff merger, that shareholder can request appraisal rights.

154 See id.

155 See Yoon-jae Han, Gook-nae sang-jang-sa chut gi-up-boon-hal [First Corporate Spinof of a Domestic Listed Company], CHOSUN ILBO, May 7, 1999

156 Appraisal rights used to be limited to publicly listed companies. See SEA art. 191.

157 See 1995 KCC arts. 335-2, 335-6 (transfer restrictions), art. 374-2 (sig¬nificant sale or purchase of business operations), art. 522-3 (mergers), and art. 530-11 (spinoff mergers). Article 374-2 specifically applies to: (1) the sale of a company’s entire business operations or a significant portion of it

2000] KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AMENDMENTS 305

Shareholders must notify the company of their objection before the relevant shareholders’ meeting and then request appraisal rights within twenty days after the shareholders’ meeting.158 The com¬pany must then purchase the shareholder’s stock within two months of this request.

In the case of restricted shares, shareholders must first notify the board of directors in writing of their intention to sell their shares to a certain person.159 The board of directors must notify the share¬holders within one month after receiving this notice as to whether they approve the transfer.160 If the board rejects the transfer, then the shareholders may ask that the company designate an appropriate recipient to purchase the shares or may demand appraisal rights. 161

In any case, when a company repurchases a shareholder’s stock based on appraisal rights, the price is determined by consensus be¬tween the shareholder and the company.162 If they cannot agree to a price, an accounting expert or a court is supposed to determine the price. If more than thirty percent of the dissenting shareholders dis¬agree with the price decided by the accounting expert, they can re¬quest that a court decide the appropriate price. 163

After the price is determined and the stock is repurchased, the company must eventually dispose of the stock in due time.164 If several dissenting shareholders exist, one question that arises is whether the company must repurchase the various shares at the same price. The explanatory background of 1998 KCC, while not authoritative, suggests that the repurchase can be at the same price if the individual shareholders agree with the company. 165

3.7. Preferred Stock

A notable goal of the new KCC is to revitalize the largely de¬funct preferred stock market in Korea. First issued in 1986 by the Oriental Brewery Company, preferred stock has been considered a

See 1995 KCC art. 374-2. See id. art. 335-2, para. 1. See id. para. 2.

See id. para. 4.

See 1995 KCC art. 335-5. See id. art. 374-2, para. 4. See id. art. 341-2, para. 3.

See Explanatory Notes, supra note 83, at 122.

failure in Korea.166 Prices of preferred stock have continued to hover at discounts of over fifty percent of the price of common stock, reflecting the lack of investor interest. 167

The collapse of the price of preferred shares in Korea can be at¬tributed to the fact that they have not offered any tangible benefits, especially when compared to common stock. Without exception, shares of preferred stock in Korea have been nonvoting and divi¬dend-giving.168 The voting rights of preferred stock were usually cancelled in return for a “preferred” dividend.169 The problem was that the preferred dividends were too meager to offset the loss of the voting rights. With the increasing importance of the mergers and acquisitions market, preferred stock without voting rights in par¬ticular became increasingly unpopular. 170

Preferred stock dividends were determined by merely adding one percent to the dividends given to common stock. 171 This sim¬plistic method of calculation was used because Article 344 of the previous Commercial Code only provided that dividends had to be “preferred” to the amount of dividends awarded to common stock, without any further explanation as to what “preferred” meant. Di¬vidends for common stock were already at a low level and typically awarded based on par value.172 Therefore, in determining the preferred dividend, one percent of the minimum 5000 won (U.S. $4.17) par value of stock, or fifty won (U.S. $0.04), was added to whatever dividends common stockholders received. 173

To enhance the appeal of preferred stock, instead of paying a preferred stock dividend that merely fluctuated according to the di

166 See Chan-hyung Chung, Woo-sun -joo [Preferred Stock], GO-SHI-GYE, Mar. 1995, at 29.

167 The discount rate has been increasing recently with the advent of new preferred stock. See Analysis of Listing and Current Market Price of Preferred Stock, Public Disclosure Department, KSE Press Release, at 6-7 (July 30, 1999) (on file with author).

168 See Chan-hyung Chung, supra note 166. Preferred stock has also been nonparticating and noncumulative for dividend payments, and preferred stock that provides stock dividends or preferred distribution in the case of dissolution has not existed. See id.

169 KCC arts. 344, 370.

170 See Chan-hyung Chung, supra note 166.

171 See id.

172 See infra Section 3.8 for a further description of the generally low div i¬dend policy.

173 See Bup -jae hyun-an [Current Legislative Issues], National Assembly Sa¬moo-chuh, 95-15, at 8-9 (Oct. 24, 1995).

2000] KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AMENDMENTS 307

vidends given to common stock, companies must now set in their articles of incorporation a minimum dividend that will be granted to preferred stockholders.174 This stipulation adds predictability and encourages higher dividends. As a result, most companies have fixed their minimum preferred stock dividends at nine percent of the 5000 won par value, which equals 450 won (U.S. $0.38).175 Preferred stock that provides stock dividends or preferred distrib u¬tion in the case of dissolution does not have to follow this minimum requirement.176 This new minimum requirement does not apply ret¬roactively and only applies to preferred stock issued after October 1, 1996.177

Finally, to encourage the issuance of preferred stocks that award their dividends in the form of stock instead of cash, stock dividends can now be paid as any type of stock.178 This means preferred stockholders can conceivably receive stock dividends in either preferred stock or even common stock.179

174 See 1995 KCC art. 344. In February 1997, the Korea Green Cross Corpo¬ration was the first company to issue preferred stock with a minimum dividend. See Seung-il Hong, Choe -juh-bae-dang-ryul bo -jang joo-shik deung -jang [Mini¬mum Dividend Guaranteed Stock Appear], JOONGANG ILBO, Mar. 19, 1997.

175 Forty-five percent of preferred stocks listed under the new regulations have set their minimum dividend at nine percent. See Jeong Hwan Wui, Shin¬hyung woo-sun -joo bal-haeng gae-hwoek sang -jang-hwoe-sa jun-chae-ui jul-ban [Half of Listed Companies Plan to Issue New Preferred Shares], MAEIL BUS. NEWS, Mar. 27, 1997.

176 See 1998 KCC art. 344.

177 Article 4 of the Addendum to the 1995 KCC states that the provisions of Article 344 will only apply to preferred stocks issued after October 1, 1996, and will not apply retroactively to previously issued stock.

178 See 1995 KCC art. 462-2, para. 1.

179 See Explanatory Notes, supra note 83, at 168-69. One question that re¬mains is whether shareholders of previously issued preferred stock who receive newly issued stock should receive preferred stock according to the new rules that stipulate the minimum preferred dividend or according to the old rules that do not. According to an advisory opinion issued by the Korean Securities Supervisory Board, “old preferred stock” should continue to receive the same type of old preferred stock when receiving new issuances. See Moo-sang -jeung -ja woo-sun¬joo-bae -jung ‘non-lan’ [‘Dispute’ over Distribution of Preferred Stock], KOREA ECON. DAILY, Sept. 26, 1996. In April 1998, the Stock Supervisory Board was merged into the Financial Supervisory Service. See Financial Supervisory Co m¬mission (visited Nov. 1, 1999) <http://www.fsc.go.kr>.

3.8. Dividends

As mentioned earlier, a critical problem has been that dividends for common stock have been woefully inadequate.180 In 1997, for instance, the average dividend yield in Korea was 3.22%. From 1994 to 1998, companies averaged between 403 won (U.S. $0.36) and 475 won (U.S. $0.40) in dividends per share.181 Companies de¬clared only the bare minimum dividend needed to meet the listing requirements or regulatory standards.182

Without sufficient dividend income, the investment goals for investors naturally shifted to short-term speculative trading instead of long-term capital gains.183 In a vicious circle, short-term inve s¬tors would not persevere in monitoring or pressuring management for higher dividends, management would not feel obligated to de¬clare more dividends than necessary, and, with low dividends, shareholders would lose their incentive for long-term investment.

The 1995 KCC introduced a variety of incentives in an attempt to boost dividends, especially stock dividends. First, as mentioned previously, companies may now award stock dividends in any type of stock they wish.184 This additional potential enhances the options, and hence the attractiveness, of stocks. Second, a new calculation method has been developed for stock dividends. When the stock dividend to be awarded is less than one share and amounts only to fractional shares, companies may combine those fractional shares and either auction them or sell the stock on the stock market and then return the monetary proceeds as dividends to the share

180 See Jae-oh Yoon, Ol joo-chong bae-dang yang-geuk-hwa ddoo-ryut [Amount of Dividends Declared at This Year’s Shareholders’ Meetings Clearly Diverge], MAEIL BUS. NEWS, Mar. 21, 1999.

181 See KOREA LISTED CO. ASS’N, 12 WOL GYUL-SAN SANG-JANG-HWOE-SA 1998 GYUL-SAN-SHIL-JUK MIT JAE-MOO-BOON-SUK [1998 ACCOUNT STATISTICS AND FINANCIAL ANALYSIS OF DECEMBER ACCOUNT LISTED COMPANIES] 16 (Apr.

1999) (on file with author).

182 To be listed on the First Section [Jae-1-bu] of the KSE, a company with a par value of 5000 won must issue at least a 300 won dividend. If a company does not issue dividends in two of the past three years, it will drop to the Second Sec¬tion [Jae-2-bu]. See KSE, Yu-ga-jeung-kwon-sang-jang-gyu-jung [Regulations on Listing Securities] arts. 31.3, 32.5.

183 See KSE Press Release, supra note 37.

184 1995 KCC art. 462-2.

2000] KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AMENDMENTS 309

holder.185 In the past, the KCC did not provide for methods of cal¬culating fractional shares. 186

Even more significantly, under the 1998 KCC, directors can de¬clare cash dividends within a given year on a one-time basis. This option must be provided for in the company’s articles of incorpora¬tion.187 Directors, however, must be careful when declaring interim dividends. If they declare interim dividends when the company lacks sufficient net assets on its balance sheet, the directors will be held jointly and severally liable for the difference.188 Directors can only avoid this type of liability if they demonstrate that they have met their duty of care.189 According to the Korea Stock Exchange, of the 516 listed companies with fiscal years ending in December 1998, forty-one have included a provision in their articles of incor¬poration that allows for interim dividends.190

Finally, companies must award dividends within one month af¬ter the shareholders’ meeting at which the dividends were approved, unless shareholders have decided otherwise.191 The time period was shortened from two months because companies would consistently force shareholders to wait the full two-month period.192

3.9. Capital Accumulation, Par Value, Stock Splits, and Stock Options

Companies can raise capital more efficiently under the various revisions to the KCC. After incorporating, companies can set the amount of authorized stock according to their needs. In earlier KCC versions, firms could not increase their authorized stock more than four times the previous amount.193 Every time this relative

185 See id.

186 See Explanatory Notes, supra note 83, at 168-69.

187 See 1998 KCC arts. 462-3.

188 See id.

189 See id.

190 See Sung-won Lee, Dae-duk-san-up deung 22 sa aek-myun boon-hal: 12 wol bup-in jung-gwan byun-gyung [December Accounting Year Companies Make Changes in Articles of Incorporation: Daeduk Industries and 22 Other Compani¬es Provide for Stock Splits], MAEIL BUS. NEWS, Mar. 30, 1999.

191 See 1998 KCC art. 344 and 1998 KCC art. 464-2. Interim dividends must be awarded one month after they are declared by the board of directors. See 1998 KCC art. 464-2.

192 See Explanatory Notes, supra note 83, at 173.

193 See 1995 KCC art. 437, limiting the amount of authorized stock. This section was repealed in 1995.

limit was reached, companies had to call a shareholders’ meeting to increase the authorized stock by amending the articles of incorpo¬ration. The revision seeks to make it less cumbersome for firms to

attract capital. 194

The restrictions governing the issuance of bonds have also been eased. Under the revised Article 470, companies can issue bonds up to four times the amount of assets provided on their balance sheet from the previous accounting year.195 Previously, companies were limited to twice the sum of their stated capital and reserves or, if total assets were less than this sum, twice their total assets. 196

The 1995 KCC allows holders of convertible bonds or bonds with warrants to convert their bonds even when the shareholder list has been closed for recording purposes prior to the shareholders’ meeting.197 This makes bonds more attractive by giving bondhold¬ers added liquidity. Bonds converted to stock can not be used to participate at the shareholders’ meeting for which the shareholder list has been closed.198

The 1998 KCC aims to increase corporate liquidity and allow companies to raise capital more easily in other ways. First, the minimum par value of stocks has been dramatically lowered from 5000 won (U.S. $4.17) to 100 won (U.S. $0.08).199 While Korea still does not allow non-par value stock, lowering the minimum par value helps entities, such as venture companies, to raise capital more effectively.

Korean corporations can now execute stock splits.200 Stock splits require a special majority shareholder vote and must follow the same procedures used for stock mergers.201 In conjunction with the lower minimum par value, stock splits have become easier to achieve. They enhance liquidity and allow stock prices to be ad¬justed to make mergers and acquisitions more attractive. Stock splits are increasingly gaining in popularity: of the 516 listed com

194 See Explanatory Notes, supra note 83, at 156-57.

195 See 1995 KCC art. 470.

196 See id.

197 See id. arts. 516, 516-10.

198 See id. arts. 350, 516, 516-9.

199 See 1998 KCC art. 329. But see Ki-won Choi, supra note 35 (arguing that the par value should not have been lowered below the 1962 requirement of 500 won (U.S. $0.41)).

200 See 1998 KCC art. 329-2.

201 See id. arts. 440 to 444.

2000] KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AMENDMENTS 311

panies with fiscal years ending in December 1998, twenty-two companies decided to carry out stock splits, resulting in lower par values.202

Finally, unlisted companies can issue stock options in the same manner as listed companies.203 Companies can issue stock options at a predetermined rate to directors, auditors and employees after a special majority vote. Shareholders who have more than ten per¬cent of the issued shares, those who have “actual influence” in the election or termination of directors or auditors, or direct relatives of any of these persons, are specifically ineligible to receive stock op¬tions. The total amount of stock options cannot exceed ten percent of the total number of issued shares. Persons with stock options can exercise them after holding their position for at least two years after the special majority shareholder vote to issue the stock options. Stock options are not transferable, but may be inherited.

4. THE CHANGING CORPORATE LANDSCAPE

The recent amendments to the KCC have helped reshape Ko¬rea’s corporate environment. The most visible developments affect corporate governance. A host of practically defunct, but critical, legal provisions in the KCC were used for the first time. For exam¬ple, the lower shareholder holding requirements have helped once passive shareholders, particularly those with nonprincipal interests, to assert their rights in an unprecedented fashion.204 Shareholders

202 See Bong-kwon Park, Aek-myon-boon-hal gi-up si -jang-soo-ik-ryul 3 bae i-sang cho-gwa-soo-ik-ryul ol-lyuh [Companies that Split Stock Had Profit Yields Three Times Greater Than that of Market Yields], MAEIL BUS. NEWS, Mar. 24, 1999.

203 See 1999 KCC arts. 340-2 to 340-5, 341-2

204 See Mark L. Clifford, The Stars of Asia, BUS. WK. INT’L EDITION, June

29, 1998, at 70

have brought the first-ever derivative actions against directors and have even made challenges for corporate control. 205

Although not yet numerous, hostile takeover bids have been at¬tempted and target companies have learned to employ various types of defensive tactics. 206 The first successful hostile takeover under the SEA is considered to be Savoy Hotel’s acquisition of Shinsung Trading.207

A confluence of other factors has increased the effectiveness of the changes to the KCC. Upon realizing that they have rights, shareholders are becoming more active participants in corporate af¬fairs.208 Investors are challenging management regarding decisions, performance, and misconduct.209 Foreign investors are also assum¬ing a more demanding presence, acquiring companies, and ques¬tioning management.210 The urgency of the financial crisis forced companies to place an emphasis on shareholder value in order to attract large-scale capital infusions and accept debt for equity swaps. This led to a relinquishment or co-sharing of management control in many cases. Several notable examples will be examined to illus

205 See infra notes 256-60 and accompanying text for a discussion of the first derivative action.

206 Some recent target companies where management control was challenged include Caproraktam, Hangdo Merchant Bank, Ulsan Merchant Bank and Mi¬dopa. See Byung-gi Hong, Caproraktam joo-chong-suh ddo kyuk-dol [Another Collision at Caproraktam’s Shareholders’ Meeting], JOONGANG ILBO, Feb. 28, 1996

CHOSUN ILBO, Dec. 11, 1996.

207 See Hun-soo Kim, Shin-sung-moo -yuk M&A ma-moo-ri [M&A of Shin¬sung Trading Completed], MAEIL BUS. NEWS, Nov. 27, 1997

CHOSUN ILBO, Aug. 1, 1997.

208 See Hong-ryul Chun, supra note 110, at 77.

209 See Hae-won Choi, In Seoul: South Korean Companies Bend to Assuage Activists, ASIAN WALL ST. J., Mar. 24, 1999, at 13

210 See discussion infra Section 4.4.

2000] KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AMENDMENTS 313

trate how the new corporate regulations and the new environment have affected corporate Korea.

4.1. The Kickof: Daehan Pulp and Oriental Brewery

In October 1996, the first signs of a changing corporate envi¬ronment emerged. On October 22, 1996, eighteen minority share¬holders of Daehan Pulp requested the convening of a special share¬holders’ meeting to terminate the chairman of the board of directors.211 This request for a special shareholders’ meeting was considered the first case in which shareholders formally exercised their shareholder rights since the enactment of the KCC in 1962.212 Shareholders sought to hold Daehan Pulp’s management account¬able for losses they suffered when Daehan Pulp initially disclosed and then withdrew its intentions to enter the telecommunications

sector. 2 13

Management, in contrast, claimed they were victims of stock manipulation and that the shareholder action itself was being led by manipulators.214 Eventually, before a court decision was reached, this dispute was settled when the shareholders dropped their request and reached an agreement with Daehan Pulp’s management.215 This case nevertheless had significant precedential value and opened a new dimension in relations between shareholders and management.

Shortly after the Daehan Pulp case, shareholders of the Oriental Brewery (“OB”) company followed suit and in November 1996, exercised their shareholder rights. The OB case arose when a sub¬sidiary of OB sought to expand its market presence in certain re

211 See Young-soo Kim, Daehan Pulp/Too -ja -ja son-shil-ip-hin dae -pyo-i-sa twoe -jin -yo-goo [Daehan Pulp: Demanding the Removal of the Representative Director that Caused Losses to Investors], CHOSUN ILBO, Nov. 7, 1996, at 13

212 See Dong-han Lee, Jip -joong boon-suk: So-aek -joo -joo woon-dong [Spe¬cial Focus: Minority Shareholder Movement], CHOSUN ILBO, Apr. 2, 1999, at 12

213 See Sang-hoon Song, Debate over Request, supra note 211.

214 See Young-soo Kim, “Dae-han -pulp” bon-gyuk-dae-gyul dol-ip [Serious Challenge for Daehan Pulp Begins], CHOSUN ILBO, Nov. 8, 1996.

215 See Jin-woo Lee, Daehan Pulp so-aek -joo -joo “joo-chong-so ” chui-ha [Daehan Pulp Small Shareholders Withdraw Shareholders’ Meeting Action], MAEIL BUS. NEWS, Jan. 8, 1997, at 21.

gional markets and sell soju, a Korean liquor, directly in competi¬tion with several local manufacturers. 216

In response to this challenge, three local soju companies joined forces and began acquiring shares in OB as a countermeasure. Af¬ter acquiring a fifteen percent stake in OB, they then requested the first-ever inspection of a company’s corporate books.217 This type of shareholder strategy was one of the first of its kind. Given gen¬erally opaque Korean accounting practices, a request for an inspec¬tion would be a considerable challenge to almost any company be¬cause it could expose sensitive financial information and accounting irregularities. OB countered that this inspection request was an abuse of shareholder rights to intimidate it into withdrawing from the regional soju markets.218

On January 24, 1997, the Seoul District Court issued an opinion approving the petition to inspect OB’s books.219 This decision be¬came the first case where a court formally recognized the exercise of a shareholder’s rights under the KCC.220 The Court held that the shareholders had met the necessary holding requirement and were therefore entitled to exercise their legally guaranteed rights. Ulti

216 See Sang-hoon Song, ‘Gyung-wol ji-bang -jin-chool’ bup -jung-ssa-woom [Legal Battle over ‘Gyungwol’s Entry into Regional Market’], JOONGANG ILBO, Nov. 19, 1996 [hereinafter Sang-hoon Song, Legal Battle].

217 For another recent example of a court finding that shareholders have a right to inspect a company’s records provided they have a legitimate reason and meet the relevant holding requirement, see Judgment Mar. 11, 1998, Seoul Ji¬bang-bup-won [District Court], Jae 19 Min-sa-bu [19th Civil Division], 97 Kahap 68790.

218 See Sang-hoon Song, Legal Battle, supra note 216.

219 See Sang-ryul Lee, Ji-bang-so -joo 3 gae-sa-ae OB jang-boo yol-lam huh¬yong [Three Local Soju Companies Allowed to Inspect OB’s Books], JOONGANG ILBO, Jan. 23, 1997, at 4

Monitor Corporate Management], JOONGANG ILBO, Jan. 24, 1997, at 5

220 See Jung-hwan Wui, supra note 219. In a subsequent opinion, the Seoul High Court reversed a lower court decision and found that the company has the burden to prove that a shareholder’s request is unreasonable. See Myung-jin Lee, [Bup-won] Gyung-young jal-mot ib -jeung mot-hae-do ju -ju jang-bu yol-lam-gyon bo-jang, [Courts: Shareholder’s Inspection Rights Guaranteed Even if Mis¬mangement Not Proven], CHOSUN ILBO, Dec. 25, 1998. Gyo-chang Kim sug¬gested earlier that companies should have the burden of proof. See Gyo-chang Kim, Sang-bup -joong hwoe-sa -pyun-ui gae -jung-ui-gyun [Opinion on the Amendment of the Stock Corporation Section of the Korean Commercial Code], L. TIMES (Seoul), Mar. 12, 1998, at 14.

2000] KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AMENDMENTS 315

mately, the inspection was not carried out because the parties reached a compromise. Nevertheless, both the Daehan Pulp and OB cases were significant because they awakened shareholders and corporate Korea to the potential impact and importance of share¬holder rights.221

4.2. Challenges to Corporate Control: Hanwha Merchant Bank and Midopa Department Store

In another notable episode in Korean corporate history, a long¬standing minority investor attempted to assume control of a finan¬cial institution. This challenge was significant not only as the first major takeover attempt in Korea, but furthermore because the target, Hanwha Merchant Bank (“HMB”), was a subsidiary of a chaebol conglomerate, the Hanwha Group.222 Ui-song Park, the second lar¬gest shareholder, amassed a near dominant forty percent of the out¬standing shares of HMB, primarily through his company, Woo¬poong Mutual Savings and Finance, and another friendly partner.223 On December 6, 1996, Park announced that he had filed a petition with the Seoul District Court requesting specific performance to convene a special shareholders’ meeting so that he could claim control of the management of the company. 224

While corporate Korea looked on in great anticipation, on Janu¬ary 7, 1997, the board of HMB employed a surprising takeover de¬fense. They nullified Park’s efforts through a private placement of forty billion won (U.S. $33.3 million) in convertible bonds (“CB”) to three friendly partners.225 The three pro-management parties that acquired the convertible bonds then immediately converted the bonds into stock. These white squires gained seventeen percent of

221 See Joo-byung Park, So-soo -joo -joo-deul gwon-li-haeng-sa neul-uh-nan¬da [More Cases of Shareholders Exercising Their Rights], KOREA ECON. DAILY, Jan. 3, 1997.

222 See Sang-hoon Song & Shin-sung Shik, Dae-gi-up sang-dae gook-nae chut M&A [First Domestic M&A of a Large Conglomerate], JOONGANG ILBO, Dec. 7, 1996, at 1

ASIAN WALL ST. J., Dec. 9, 1996, at 3.

223 See Sang-hoon Song & Shin-sung Shik, supra note 222

224 See Sang-hoon Song & Shin-sung Shik, supra note 222.

225 The three friendly partners were Samshin-Allstate, HiFive, and Donghung Electric. See Myung-soo Suh, Han-wha -jong-geum sa-mo-sa-chae jun-kyuk bal-haeng [Hanwha Merchant Bank Issues Private Placement of CBs],

JOONGANG ILBO, Jan. 9, 1997, at 3.

the total voting shares of HMB and helped management to success¬fully dilute shares favorable to Park.226

Park, in turn, challenged management’s takeover defense. He attempted to enjoin the voting rights of the management-friendly shareholders who purchased the convertible bonds.227 He claimed that the issuance of the convertible bonds by HMB’s management to protect their control violated their fiduciary duty under the KCC.228 Although sympathetic to Park’s claim, the Seoul District Court ultimately rejected Park’s arguments.229 The District Court stated that, despite the interests of shareholders, the voting rights stemming from the convertible bonds could not be cancelled at that stage because the instruments had been already issued and convert¬ed into stock.230 The court was concerned that denying the voting rights of the stock would undermine the “safety of the market.”231 With their additional voting power secured, Hanwha narrowly de¬feated Park’s takeover attempts at the special shareholders’ meeting held on February 13, 1997.232

This district court ruling was problematic for a number of rea¬sons. The converted stocks in question had yet to be listed

226 See Myung-soo Suh, Han-wha -jong-geum sa-mo CB chut joo-shik jun¬hwan [Hanwha Merchant Bank Privately Placed CB Converted into Stock],

JOONGANG ILBO, Jan. 12, 1997, at 1.

227 See KCC art. 424.

228 See Byung-il Yeh, Han-wha -jong-geum: Gyung-young-gwon hyang-bang bup-won-su pan-ga-reum-nal-dut [Hanwha Merchant Bank: Appears the Future of Management Control Will Be Decided by the Courts], CHOSUN ILBO, Jan. 9, 1997. Fourteen minority shareholders also brought suit against the issuance of the convertible bonds. Han-wha -jong-geum so-aek -joo -joo so-song [Minority Shareholders of Hanwha Merchant Sue], JOONGANG ILBO, Jan. 11, 1997, at 1.

229 See Judgment of Feb. 6, 1997, Seoul Chi-bang-bup-won [District Court], Jae 50 Min-sa-bu [50th Civil Division], 97 Kkahap 118

230 See Judgment of Feb. 6, 1997, supra note 229.

231 Id.

232 See Sang-hoon Song, Han-wha “Jong-geum gyung -young-gwon ” bang¬uh [Hanwha Defends Challenge Against “Merchant Bank Management”], JOONGANG ILBO, Feb. 14, 1997, at 26.

2000] KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AMENDMENTS 317

Park requested an injunction to cancel the convertible bonds.233 The Seoul High Court, in turn, agreed that the issuance of the converti¬ble bonds should be cancelled because they infringed on the rights of shareholders.234 The court cited that the primary purpose of the issuance of the bonds was to defend management’s control. 235 However, the High Court ultimately deferred judgment on whether the voting rights should be denied.

During this dramatic series of events, several rarely-employed provisions of the KCC were once again used. Park’s request for a special shareholders’ meeting, for instance, was considered to be only the second case, after Daehan Pulp, of a shareholder in Korea bringing such a request.236 Next, as with the OB case, Park asked for an inspection of the corporate books.237 Third, the special shareholders’ meeting that was held produced the first-ever proxy fight in Korea.238 This battle for control eventually became moot when HMB was declared insolvent.239

At about the same time as the HMB case, another major hostile takeover attempt occurred. On January 23, 1997, Dongbang Pere¬grine Securities announced that it wished to elect a new manage¬ment for Midopa Department Store.240 Midopa was the flagship company of the thirty-fourth largest conglomerate in Korea, the Dainong Group. Dongbang Peregrine claimed that Midopa could be managed more effectively.241 Not only did this case involve

233 See Judgment of May 13, 1997, Seoul Go-deung-bup-won [High Court], 97 Ra 36

234 See id.

235 See id.

236 KCC art. 366.

237 See Sang-hoon Song & Shin-sung Shik, supra note 222.

238 See KCC art. 368

239 See In-soo Kim, Woe-hwan-wui-gi joo-bum boo-shil -jong-geum-sa pa¬san-chuh-ri-do him-deul-uh [It’s Also Dificult to Liquidate the Main Culprits of the Foreign Currency Crisis, the Improperly Run Merchant Banks], MAEIL BUS. NEWS, Oct. 22, 1998.

240 See Byung-il Yeh, Mi-do -pa-joo-chong-suh ui-gyul-gwon haeng-sa [Ex¬ercising Shareholder Rights at the Midopa Shareholders’ Meeting], CHOSUN ILBO, Jan. 24, 1997.

241 See id. Some reports claimed that Dongbang Peregrine was merely greenmailing Midopa on behalf of unknown foreign investors that reportedly held

another challenge against a chaebol company, but it was also a ho s¬tile takeover attempt that was launched by an entirely outside con¬glomerate.

Following the Hanwha experience and other recent examples, several provisions of the KCC were utilized again. First, Dongbang Peregrine declared its interest in inspecting Midopa’s corporate books.242 Second, Shindongbang requested a special shareholders’ meeting to elect new management.243

Midopa, in the meantime, followed HMB’s strategy and issued a private placement of fifty billion won (U. S. $41.7 million) worth of convertible bonds and, later, bonds with warrants.244 In this case, however, the Seoul District Court issued an injunction preventing Midopa from offering the convertible bonds or the bonds with war¬rants. 245 The court found that the Midopa case differed from the Hanwha case because the injunction was requested before the bonds

up to 20% of Midopa’s shares. See Young-shin Yoon, Hongkong Money: gook¬nae joong-gyun-gi-up -joo jip -joong-mae -jip [Hong Kong Money: Concentrate Purchases of Stock of Middle Size Domestic Companies], CHOSUN ILBO, Feb. 7, 1997. The Securities Supervisory Board censured Dongbang-Peregrine for “ille¬gal parking,” (i.e., using a third party to acquire Midopa shares to avoid disclo¬sure requirements), which was considered one of the first such cases ever. See Byung-il Yeh, Bool-bup ‘Parking’ haeng-wui gi-seung [Illegal ‘Parking’ Prac¬tice Flourishes], CHOSUN ILBO, July 9, 1997, at 12. Ultimately, Shindongbang, the joint venture partner of Peregrine that established Dongbang-Peregrine, later emerged as the real suitor seeking to take control of Midopa. See Byung-il Yeh, Shin-dong-bang Group: Mi-do -pa -joo mae -jip hwak-in [Shindongbang Group Confirms It Purchased Midopa Shares], CHOSUN ILBO, Mar. 5, 1997. See gener¬ally Seong C. Gweon, Play a Fair Game, Please, KOREA HERALD, Mar. 12, 1997 (discussing the various financial regulations breached during the deal).

242 See Byung-il Yeh, “Mi-do -pa M&A pa-moon” joo -yok Paul Pheby, jeung-gwon -jun-moon-ga-in-ga gyo-ran -ja-in-ga [Paul Pheby, the Main Actor of the “Repercussions of the Midopa M&A”: Is He a Securities Specialist or a Market Disrupter], CHOSUN ILBO, Feb. 2, 1997.

243 See Myung-soo Suh, Shin-dong-bang, Mi-do -pa -jang-ak jun-myun-gong¬sae [Shindongbang, Frontal Ofense to Take Control of Midopa], JOONGANG ILBO, Mar. 13, 1997. Although Midopa was able to withstand Shindongbang’s challenge, in the end the entire Dainong Group and Midopa collapsed largely from the strain of defending the takeover. See Midopa Is Declared Bankrupt Af¬ter Loan Woes, ASIAN WALL ST. J., Mar. 19, 1998, at 4.

244 Midopa also attempted to issue privately placed bonds with warrants. See Sang-hoon Song, Midopa BW bal-haeng gye-hwoek moo-san [Midopa’s Plans to Issue BWs Stopped], JOONGANG ILBO, Feb. 28, 1997, at 8.

245 The bonds would have been convertible before July 1, 1997. Judgment of Feb. 27, 1997, Seoul Ji-bang-bup-won [District Court], Jae 50 Min-sa-bu [50th Civil Division], 97 Kkahap 481. See Midopa Issues Bonds in Defensive Move, ASIAN WALL ST. J., Mar. 10, 1997, at 13 [hereinafter Defensive Move].

2000] KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AMENDMENTS 319

were issued and therefore a compelling public interest to protect the market did not exist.246

While Midopa tried to defend itself, another unheard of event occurred. One of Korea’s three major investment trusts, Korea In¬vestment Trust Company (“KITC”), initially opposed Midopa’s at¬tempt to issue the privately placed convertible bonds. KITC threat¬ened that if Midopa issued the convertible bonds, in the “interest of minority shareholders and institutional shareholders,” it would transfer its 7.7% share of Midopa stock to the party threatening the takeover.247 This marked a rare occurrence of an institutional in¬vestor publicly acting on behalf of the interests of its customers against actions taken by a company in which they invested. In Ko¬rea, fund managers have tended to be passive and restrained.248

Overall, several aspects of the HMB and Midopa cases are noteworthy. First, both cases demonstrated the enormous possibil¬ities and the importance of shareholder rights.249 Second, they ex¬posed the vulnerability of corporate control in Korean companies and demonstrated that even firms within chaebol conglomerates were not immune from challenges. Although companies can no longer issue private placements of bond offerings when facing hos¬tile threats, the defensive responses by Midopa, and previously Hanwha, demonstrated the seriousness and urgency of their con

246 Midopa later issued the bonds by changing the terms so that shares could be converted after July 1, 1997, which would prevent them from being exercised at Midopa’s annual shareholders’ meeting in the fall. See Defensive Move, supra note 245.

247 Mi-do -pa sa-mo CB bal-haeng ban-dae [Korea Investment Trust Objects to Midopa’s Private Placement of CBs], CHOSUN ILBO, Jan. 31, 1997, at 1.

248 See Byung-il Yeh, Gi-gwan-too-ja-ga-deul byun-shin [Institutional In¬vestors Are Changing], CHOSUN ILBO, Feb. 1, 1997, at 8.

249 At one point there was speculation that the Shindongbang Group might try to take over not only Midopa, but also the entire Dainong Group. See Sang¬hoon Song, Dai-nong num-bo -gi … group M&A ga-neung-sung [Interest in Dainong … Possibility of a Group M&A], JOONGANG ILBO, Mar. 6, 1997. Another bizarre event indicative of the collusive ties between many chaebol con¬glomerates was that the Federation of Korean Industries, composed of the na¬tion’s top chaebols, declared that it would join forces together to defend the take¬over of Midopa. This hasty solution was quickly withdrawn after pressure from the Korean Fair Trade Commission. See Namju Cho, Korea Takes New Step, su¬pra note 48

cerns.250 In the aftermath of the Hanwha and Midopa incidents, sixty-eight companies issued such private placements of convertible bonds primarily to secure management control. 251 Although unsuc¬cessful, these two cases were nevertheless the first serious hostile takeover attempts to occur in Korean corporate history.

4.3. Seeking Management Accountability: Korea First Bank

In terms of capturing the attention of Korean management, per¬haps no event had a greater impact than the case of Korea First Bank (“KFB”), once one of Korea’s premier banks. As the primary lending bank to a string of failed chaebols that collapsed in spec¬tacular fashion, including the Hanbo Group, Kia Group, and Sammi Group, the government was forced to nationalize KFB in February 1998.252 KFB’s troubles exemplified the ineffective corporate gov¬ernance of financial intermediaries in Korea. Unchecked by share¬holders, Korean banks were always highly susceptible to outside pressures.

First, KFB management faced tough questions from organized shareholders regarding their roles in the Hanbo Group scandal dur¬ing the annual shareholders’ meeting held in March 1997. This marked one of the first times that minority shareholders systemati¬cally and vocally challenged a major corporation’s management at a shareholders’ meeting.253 Their most fundamental rights of partici

250 See SEA art. 24, SEA Implementing Decree arts. 10, 12-5

JOONGANG ILBO, Mar. 20, 1997.

251 See Tae-ung Chung, Sa-mo -jun-hwan-sa-chae bup-won -pan-kyul-ro M&A tae-ma ban-kam dwoel-deut [The Judicial Decision on Privately Placed Convertible Bonds Likely to Thwart M&A], KOREA ECON. DAILY, Feb. 9, 1997, at 4

252 See Michael Schuman, Korea Watches, Waits as Sammi Group Seeks Court Protection from Creditors, ASIAN WALL ST. J., Mar. 20, 1997, at 1.

253 See Myung -jae Lee, Jae-il-eun joo-chong . . . sung-nan so-aek -joo -joo¬deul [KFB Shareholders’ Meeting . . . Angry Minority Shareholders], DONGA

2000] KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AMENDMENTS 321

pation and voting were exercised. KFB management crudely tried to prevent shareholders from participating in the annual sharehold¬ers’ meeting and then managed to summarily steamroll through various management proposals. However, minority shareholders later brought legal actions challenging the procedural breaches, ir¬regularities, and validity of the resolutions made at this annual shareholders’ meeting.

Two significant court decisions emerged from the events sur¬rounding the failure of KFB. First, in a critical case, the Seoul Dis¬trict Court held that the resolutions of the annual shareholders’ meeting should be cancelled because of the various procedural er¬rors that occurred. They specifically cited the failure to give ob¬jecting shareholders a chance to express their views.254 The Court stated that its decision disregarded how companies may have con¬ducted shareholders’ meetings in the past. For the first time, a court accepted a minority shareholder’s petition to cancel resolutions that were passed at a shareholders’ meeting.255

Next, furious KFB stockholders initiated the first-ever share¬holder derivative action in Korea.256 Shareholders claimed that over

ILBO (Seoul), Mar. 8, 1997, at 37. Minority shareholders also raised serious challenges at KFB’s 1998 and 1999 shareholders’ meetings. See Tae-ung Chung & Hong-yul Kim, Eun-heng sal -ja-go so-aek -joo -joo da jook-ih-na [Sacrificing All the Minority Shareholders to Save the Bank], KOREA ECON. DAILY, Mar. 3, 1999

254 See Judgment of Dec. 12, 1997, Seoul Chi-bang-bup-won [District Court], Jae 22 Hap-ui-min-sa-bu [22nd Civil Division], 97 Kahap 32890

255 See Lee & Bang, supra note 254. On appeal, however, the Seoul High Court reversed the cancellation of the resolutions of the shareholders’ meeting primarily because of the overwhelming consequences to shareholders and the Ko¬rean economy that would have resulted. See Judgment of Aug. 25, 1998, Seoul Go-deung-bup-won [High Court], Jae 9 Min-sa-boo, 98 Na 5267. The High Court did emphasize that otherwise it would be proper to cancel the resolutions of the meeting.

256 See Dae-yon Kim, Joo -joo-dae -pyo-so-song-gwa gyong-young -pan-dan¬ui-won-chik [Shareholder Derivative Actions and the Business Judgment Rule], 17 COM. L. REV. 111 (1999)

1.1 trillion won (U.S. $916.6 million) in bad loans to the Hanbo Group in particular led to over 270 billion won (U.S. $225 million) in losses to the bank.257 KFB management allegedly received bribes in return for these loans. In a historic decision, the Seoul District Court not only found KFB directors responsible for mismanage¬ment and misconduct, but awarded a record forty billion won (U.S. $33.3 million) judgment against four former KFB directors on be¬half of the shareholders.258

The compensatory award of the shareholder derivative action and the cancellation of the shareholders’ meeting had a powerful impact on the burgeoning shareholder movement.259 The cases served to impress upon Korean management the importance of their responsibilities and duties to their shareholders and the conse¬quences they may face as a result of their decisions.260

4.4. Monitoring Management Decisions: Samsung Electronics and SK Telecom

Recent investor pressure against some of Korea’s premier blue chip companies has sent a powerful message that all companies

Shareholders of KFB Bring Suit Against Directors], CHOSUN ILBO, Apr. 11, 1997

257 PSPD was able to gather 894,702 shares to barely meet the new lowered 0.5% holding requirement of 820,000 shares under the SEA that became effective April 1, 1997. See Hong-yul Kim, supra note 256.

258 See Judgment of July 24, 1998, Seoul Chi-bang-pop-won [District Court], Jae 17 Min-sa-hap-ui-bu [17th Civil Division], 98 Kahap 39907

259 See Dae-yon Kim, supra note 256, at 111-12. Other notable examples of shareholder lawsuits that were raised thereafter include an action brought by mi¬nority shareholders against Korea Telecom and Samsung Electronics. See In¬soon Kim, supra note 69

260 See Kang-eun Lee, So-aek -joo -joo-dae -pyo chut seung-so/ui-mi-wa gwa¬jang [First Shareholder Derivative Suit Victory/Meaning and Impact], DONGA ILBO, July 24, 1998, at 3.

2000] KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AMENDMENTS 323

must pay heed to their shareholders.261 In March 1998, organized shareholders attended the Samsung Electronics Corporation’s annu¬al shareholders’ meeting and questioned its management about a variety of business decisions at unprecedented levels.262 Instead of a somnolent and scripted thirty-minute affair, the meeting lasted for a record sixteen hours.263

Shareholders proceeded to exercise their various newfound rights under the KCC. Shareholders first requested an inspection of the contents of the board of directors’ minutes.264 The management of Samsung Electronics initially did not comply with this request, but changed its position when the Suwon District Court issued a three million won fine against it.265 Shareholders then commenced a shareholder derivative action against various directors of Samsung Electronics on several counts. The action included claims con¬cerning bribes paid to two former presidents and illegal trading with its subsidiaries.266 These various events forced many to realize that even Korea’s premier companies must not disregard the interests of

261 See Hae-won Choi, supra note 209, at 13 (noting that “[i]nvestors are watching a new indicator in South Korea: minority-shareholder activism”)

262 See Namju Cho, Halting Pace of Korea Inc. Reforms Is Highlighted: Samsung Electronics Meeting Indicates Shareholders Have Far to Go in Assert¬ing Themselves, ASIAN WALL ST. J., Mar. 30, 1998, at 4. The management of Samsung Electronics was specifically questioned on its relation to Samsung’s disastrous venture into the automobile industry and its near billion dollar failed investment in the U.S. personal computer manufacturer AST. Shareholders also challenged the propriety of Samsung Electronics’ private issuance of convertible bonds to the son of the chairman of the Samsung Group at a tremendous discount. See id.

263 See id. In the 1999 annual shareholders’ meeting, shareholders raised ad¬ditional issues. Attempts to negotiate a compromise failed, and Samsung Elec¬tronics was able to obtain the necessary votes to amend its articles of incorpora¬tion to exclude cumulative voting. See Young-i Lee, So-aek -ju -ju 4-dae-group ju-chong kyuk-dol [Minority Shareholders of 4 Major Groups Clash at Share¬holder Meetings], DONGA ILBO, Mar. 21, 1999.

264 See KCC art. 396.

265 See Hyo -jae Lee, I-sa-hwoi-gi-rok yeol-lam-guh-bu, chae-bol-ae gwa¬tae-ryo bu-gwa [Rejection of Inspection of Board of Directors Minutes Leads to Fine Against Chaebol], CHOSUN ILBO, June 13, 1998.

266 See Myung -jin Lee, [Cham -yuh -yon-dae] Sam-sung -jun -ja gyung -young¬jin-sang-dae son-hae-bae-sang [PSPD Files a Compensatory Action Against SEC’s Management], CHOSUN ILBO, Oct. 20, 1998.

their shareholders and helped reorient companies to understanding that management must in fact respect the interests of their share

holders. 267

In contrast, at about the same time in March 1998, the manage¬ment of SK Telecom (“SKT”) accepted a host of shareholder de¬mands before its annual shareholders’ meeting. 268 Such an accep¬tance was a milestone in Korean corporate history. This agreement followed the first proxy solicitation initiated by a foreign share¬holder.269 SKT’s management not only agreed to elect two outside directors and an independent auditor, but also agreed to accept the candidates chosen by shareholders to act in these positions.270

Next, several important amendments were made to the articles of incorporation. The new articles of incorporation provide that interconglomerate trading within the SK Group between related or sister companies that are in excess of ten billion won (U.S. $8.33 million) must be approved by a majority of the outside directors. As a result, outside directors were recently able to reclaim 300 bil¬lion won (U. S. $216 million) that was subsidized in the form of commercial paper to several sister companies.271 SKT also agreed

267 See Don Kirk, Shareholders Take on Big Seoul Firms, INT’L HERALD TRIB., Mar. 22, 1999, at 11 (“Shareholders’ meetings, traditionally pro forma af¬fairs in which the executives of large companies faced no criticism, much less opposition, took a different turn this year because of South Korea’s economic cri¬sis.”).

268 See Seong C. Gweon, supra note 241

269 See Gwang-am Chun, ‘Tiger’ deung 4 gae woe-gook-gae fund SK Tele¬com ‘Joo -joo-gwon’ noon-dok [Four Foreign Funds Including Tiger Eye ‘Share¬holder Rights’ in SK Telecom], DONGA ILBO, Mar. 17, 1998, at 21.

270 See Jon E. Hilsenrath, Directors Get Tough with SK Telecom, ASIAN WALL ST. J, Sept. 29, 1998, at 1 [hereinafter Hilsenrath, Directors Get Tough]

271 See Hilsenrath, Directors Get Tough, supra note 270, at 1

2000] KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AMENDMENTS 325

to recover 300,000 shares that were improperly given to a sister company.272 Overall, in 1998, outside directors amended six out of twelve interconglomerate deals that they reviewed and rejected two deals altogether.273 These efforts by outside directors and auditors in particular were among the most successful examples of internal supervision under the new corporate environment.274

Despite this progress in 1998, management consistently rejected various proposals by shareholders in 1999. First, they amended the company’s articles of incorporation to exclude cumulative voting.275 Furthermore, SKT’s outside auditor became the first auditor to call a shareholders’ meeting under the newly established Article 412-3. The auditor convened the meeting because of his objections to a controversial new stock issue.276

Nevertheless, SKT’s management was praised for its initial willingness to accept a considerable degree of the proposals by its shareholders at the time.277 Some skeptics, of course, claim that these changes were only possible because management could not afford to ignore foreign investors, who held more than a thirty-three percent stake at the time.278 Yet, SKT announced it would be will¬ing to establish an audit committee for the company, one of the first

272 See Hwang, supra note 271, at 27.

273 See Sa-woe i-sa: sung-gong sa-rae-SK Telecom [Outside Directors: A Successful Case-SK Telecom], MAEIL BUS. NEWS, Mar. 16, 1999.

274 See id. (citing how, unlike other corporations, the outside directors held over 80 discussion meetings and how outside directors were selected by minority shareholders).

275 This became possible because, in contrast to the government’s overall ef¬forts to strengthen accountability and transparency through the adoption of cu¬mulative voting, the critical 18% stake of SKT held by Korea Telecom, a public enterprise, voted with management to exclude cumulative voting. See Sung-gun Cho, Jip -jung-too -pyo -jae-ui hyang-bang [The Future Direction of the Cumula¬tive Voting System], KOREA ECON. DAILY, Mar. 22, 1999.

276 See Ji-hun Lee, Chae-bol-chong-soo hae-im-an joo-chong-su chut -pyo¬gyul [First Vote at Shareholders’ Meeting on Termination of a Chaebol Chair¬man], CHOSUN ILBO, Aug. 28, 1999.

277 See Hilsenrath & Cho, supra note 204, at 1 (noting that it is “likely to be regarded as a landmark”). For comments on the limitations of the SKT case and some of the negative aspects of its management, see Jon E. Hilsenrath, Rethink¬ing Asia: The Search for Solutions, ASIAN WALL ST. J., Oct. 26, 1998, at S4

278 The limitation on foreign ownership of SKT which exists under a special law was raised to 49% as of July 1, 1999. See Electronic Communication Busi¬ness Law, Law No. 4394 of 1991 (amended Law No. 5385 of 1997), arts. 6, 7.

in Korea.279 Overall, the managerial changes accomplished in the SKT case offer a glimpse into the future of corporate governance in Korea.280

5. CONCLUSION: REORIENTATION OF CORPORATE KOREA AND

ISSUES FOR THE FUTURE

The recent revisions to the Commercial Code mark a significant transition in Korea’s corporate regulatory environment. All of these reforms should be consolidated by the following factors. First, for¬eign investors will increasingly play a larger role in Korean corpo¬rations and the utilization of the KCC.281 The ownership restric¬tions for foreign investors have been completely lifted in almost all listed companies.282 As of May 25, 1998, foreign investors are no longer restricted from hostile takeovers.283 Foreign investors, in fact, already own twenty percent of the total volume of listed stock

279 See Soon-Hyun Hwang, SK Telecom gom-sa-hyub-ui-hwoe-ui-hwoe chul¬bum [SK Telecom Establishes Audit Committee], CHOSUN ILBO, May 13, 1999.

280 One of the most significant signs of progress recently occurred when Da¬com, Korea’s leading internet service provider and part of the LG conglomerate, accepted proposals of PSPD. Among other things, Dacom agreed both to elect half of its eight directors as outside directors, and to establish an audit committee with two-thirds of its members as outside directors. Both of these measures oc¬curred one year ahead of the SEA’s requirements. PSPD has been given the right to nominate two of the outside directors. Dacom has also agreed to require that the audit committee approve interconglomerate trading and special issues of stocks and bonds. See Business in South Korea: Career Path, ECONOMIST , Apr. 1, 2000, at 59-60

281 See Hong-ryul Chun, supra note 110, at 76-77

282 The foreign ownership restriction was lifted on May 25, 1998, excluding certain public companies. See Foreign Securities Trading Regulation, Financial Supervisory Service.

283 See Foreigner Investment and Foreign Capital Inducement Act, Law No. 5538 of 1998 (amended by Foreigner Investment Promotion Act, Law No. Sept. 16, 1998).

2000] KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AMENDMENTS 327

on the Korea Stock Exchange, including majority shares in several blue chip companies.284

Representatives of foreign investors sit on the board of directors of such institutions as Korea Exchange Bank and SKT.285 While they still might be hesitant at present, companies realize that foreign investors will not be as passive as Korean shareholders. Companies with large foreign ownership must particularly pay attention.286 For instance, Samsung Electronics and SKT, which both have substan¬tial foreign ownership, have been paying heightened attention to the demands of foreign shareholders.287 Overall, a significant but subtle disciplining effect on Korean corporate governance is emerging.288

In addition to foreign investors, Korean institutional investors, which now own almost thirty-five percent of the total listed shares, are also on the brink of becoming more active actors.289 Until last year, institutional investors have been restricted in exercising their voting rights from customer accounts.290 At most, they occasionally objected to mergers or merely claimed appraisal rights.291 As wit

284 See [Joo -joo-chong-hwoe] Hot Issue . . . 5 dae group 5 gae gi-up si-kkeu¬rop-da [Hot Issues at Shareholders’ Meetings . . . Noisy at the Five Largest Companies of the Five Largest Groups], MAEIL BUS. NEWS, Mar. 3, 1999.

285 See Sara Webb, Asian Companies Open Themselves Up to Foreigners, ASIAN WALL ST. J., July 28, 1998, at 22.

286 See generally Jane L. Lee & Hae Won Choi, Korean Firms Resist Change at Key Meetings, ASIAN WALL ST. J., Mar. 22, 1999, at 1 (noting that foreign shareholders were more active in the current year’s shareholders’ meet¬ings).

287 See Bong-kwon Park, Samsung Electronics, SK Telecom, Korea Telecom deung jip -jung-too -pyo -jae bae -jae-ae woe-gook-in hyup -jo [Samsung Electron¬ics, SK Telecom, Korea Telecom Seek Cooperation of Foreigners in Excluding Cumulative Voting], MAEIL BUS. NEWS, Mar. 12, 1999.

288 See Hae-won Choi, supra note 209, at 13 (noting that “foreign investors praise the changes pushed through by minority shareholders”)

289 See KSE, Joo-shik [Stock], Apr. 1999

290 See Jae-won Lee, supra note 27, at 167-77.

291 See Gi-gwan gi-up-gyung -yong gam-shi na-sut-da [Institutional Investors Begin Monitoring Corporate Management], MAEIL BUS. NEWS, Feb. 27, 1997

nessed in the annual shareholders’ meetings that were held in the spring of 1999, overall they still remained passive.292 Most institu¬tional investors, for instance, generally abstained or voted against the adoption of cumulative voting. 293 Yet, with the explosion of closed-end funds and unit trust investment in 1999, and the conse¬quent increase in competition among institutional investors, this predisposition is likely to change.

Furthermore, Korea is facing considerable peer pressure from international organizations such as the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (“OECD”) to modify its corporate regulations to reflect newly emerging international standards.294 Korea accepted various aspects of the OECD proposals. Among the reforms adopted, outside directors must comprise one-quarter of the board of listed companies.295 Although outside directors face limitations in all corporate systems, overall they should be able to provide additional checks and balances to the management structure dominated by the principal shareholders. Moreover, large compa¬nies and securities firms with assets of over two trillion won face even stricter standards.296 First, they must elect at least three out¬side directors to their boards in 2000 and more than half by 2001.297 These outside directors also must be elected through nominating committees. Second, they must establish audit committees where more than two-thirds of their members are outside directors.298 In

292 See Hun-soo Kim & Yong-hae Choi, Jip -jung-too -pyo -jae non-lan … sang -jang-sa bae -jae-chu -jin-ae gi-gwan-too -ja-ga juh -ji na-suh [Dispute Con¬cerning Cumulative Voting … Institutional Investors Seek to Block Attempts by Listed Companies to Exclude Provision], MAEIL BUS. NEWS, Feb. 12, 1999. But cf. Jae-oh Yoon, 12 wol gyul-san sang -jang-sa joo-chong i-bun -joo-boo-tuh bon¬gyuk gae-mak [Listed Companies with Accounting Years Ending in December Commence Shareholders’ Meetings This Week], MAEIL BUS. NEWS, Feb. 21, 1999 (describing that Daehan Investment Trust and Korea Investment Trust did object to a recent merger between Hyundai Motors and Hyundai Motor Service).

293 See Hun-soo Kim & Yong-hae Choi, supra note 292.

294 See Yong-yool Kim, Woo-ri-na-ra-ui gi-up -ji-bae-goo -jo mo-bum-gyu¬yak jae -jung ui-ui-wa bang-hyang [The Meaning and Future Direction of the Establishment of Best Practices for Korean Corporate Governance], 39 SANG

JANG-HYUP 9 (1999).

295 See SEA art. 191-16.

296 See id.

297 See SEA art. 191-16, annex art. 8.

298 See SEA arts. 191-17, 54-6. See generally Bup-gae-jung jak-up so-gae [Introducing Preparations of Law Amendments], L. TIMES, Mar. 25, 1999, at 3

2000] KOREAN COMMERCIAL CODE AMENDMENTS 329

light of the significant position of financial companies, the standard holding requirements to exercise shareholders rights have been lowered by an additional fifty percent in the case of shareholders of securities companies.299

The 1995, 1998, and 1999 revisions to the KCC represent the third, fourth, and fifth amendments in a period of over thirty years. Although various changes still need to be made, unimaginable pro¬gress has been achieved at an alarming pace. The onset of the Ko¬rean financial crisis in late 1997 ironically served as a catalyst for further reforms. Korea attempted to tackle some of the central problems of its corporate regulation such as the lack of account¬ability in corporate governance, weak directors and auditors, inef¬fective shareholder rights, and transparency standards. External corporate governance has been promoted by facilitating mergers and acquisitions.

Various reforms still need to be pursued. Class actions suits are still not permitted. Although a proposed law to permit class actions has been drafted, it has continued to linger in the National Assem¬bly.300 Despite the recent amendments, the current threshold share¬ownerhip requirements still act as a barrier to the exercise of share¬holder rights and need to be lowered further.

Nevertheless, the recent amendments to Korea’s Commercial Code should increase the competitiveness of corporate Korea. In¬stead of operating in a vacuum, Korean corporations can only be¬come more efficient institutions by finally facing at least some de¬gree of monitoring controls and internal and external corporate governance discipline. These changes can only serve to enhance the international competitiveness of corporate Korea.

the Possibility of Adopting Audit Committees], 39 SANG-JANG-HYUP 51 (1999)

299 See SEA art. 64.

300 See The National Assembly of the Republic of Korea (visited Nov. 1, 1999) <http://www.assembly.go.kr>. The IMF initially requested the inclusion of class action suits. See Gyung-ho Yoon, So-soo -joo -joo jib-dan-so-song -jae [Minority Shareholder Class Action], MAEIL BUS. NEWS, Dec. 24, 1997.